首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
相似文献
 共查询到20条相似文献,搜索用时 31 毫秒
1.
Let (T,τ,μ) be a finite measure space, X be a Banach space, P be a metric space and let L1(μ,X) denote the space of equivalence classes of X-valued Bochner integrable functions on (T,τ,μ). We show that if φ:T×P→2X is a set-valued function such that for each fixed pεP, φ(·,p) has a measurable graph and for each fixed tεT, φ(t,·) is either upper or lower semicontinuous then the Aumann integral of φ, i.e.,∫Tφ(t,p)dμ(t)= {∫Tx(t)dμ(t):xεSφ(p)}, where Sφ(p)= {yεL1(μ,X):y(t)εφ(t,p)μ−a.e.}, is either upper or lower semicontinuous in the variable p as well. Our results generalize those of Aumann (1965, 1976) who has considered the above problem for X=Rn, and they have useful applications in general equilibrium and game theory.  相似文献   

2.
Nigm et al. (2003, statistics 37: 527–536) proposed Bayesian method to obtain predictive interval of future ordered observation Y (j) (r < jn ) based on the right type II censored samples Y (1) < Y (2) < ... < Y (r) from the Pareto distribution. If some of Y (1) < ... < Y (r-1) are missing or false due to artificial negligence of typist or recorder, then Nigm et al.’s method may not be an appropriate choice. Moreover, the conditional probability density function (p.d.f.) of the ordered observation Y (j) (r < jn ) given Y (1) <Y (2) < ... < Y (r) is equivalent to the conditional p.d.f. of Y (j) (r < jn ) given Y (r). Therefore, we propose another Bayesian method to obtain predictive interval of future ordered observations based on the only ordered observation Y (r), then compares the length of the predictive intervals when using the method of Nigm et al. (2003, statistics 37: 527–536) and our proposed method. Numerical examples are provided to illustrate these results.  相似文献   

3.
Summary LetN=[n ij ] (i=1, …,r;j=1, …,c) be the matrix of observed frequencies in anr×c contingency table fromr possibly different multinomial populations with respective probabilitiesp i =(p i1, …,p ic ).Freeman andHalton have proposed an exact conditional test for the hypothesisH 0 :p i =(p 1, …p c ) of the exact test is derived. Numerical values forβ(p) were previously computed for the special case:r=3,c=2 [Bennett andNakamura, 1964].  相似文献   

4.
We study the questions of existence and smoothness of demand functions with an infinite number of commodities. The main result obtained, under some hypothesis, is: if a C1 demand exists in a commodity space B, then B can be given an inner product structure. For example, if B is Lp, 1p∞, and if there exists a C1 demand function defined on B then p must be 2. Another result is: if a demand function exists, defined for all prices p and income, then the commodity space must be reflexive. For example, if B is Lp and a demand function exists on B, defined for all prices and incomes then 1<p<∞. We also study the cases L and L1 with weaker assumptions. We finish the paper proving that the demand function is always defined for a dense set of prices and convenient incomes.  相似文献   

5.
LetX 1,…,X m andY 1,…,Y n be two independent samples from continuous distributionsF andG respectively. Using a Hoeffding (1951) type theorem, we obtain the distributions of the vector S=(S (1),…,S (n)), whereS (j)=# (X i ’s≤Y (j)) andY (j) is thej-th order statistic ofY sample, under three truncation models: (a)G is a left truncation ofF orG is a right truncation ofF, (b)F is a right truncation ofH andG is a left truncation ofH, whereH is some continuous distribution function, (c)G is a two tail truncation ofF. Exploiting the relation between S and the vectorR of the ranks of the order statistics of theY-sample in the pooled sample, we can obtain exact distributions of many rank tests. We use these to compare powers of the Hajek test (Hajek 1967), the Sidak Vondracek test (1957) and the Mann-Whitney-Wilcoxon test. We derive some order relations between the values of the probagility-functions under each model. Hence find that the tests based onS (1) andS (n) are the UMP rank tests for the alternative (a). We also find LMP rank tests under the alternatives (b) and (c).  相似文献   

6.
Optimality criteria are derived for stochastic programs with convex objective and convex constraints. The problem consists in selecting x1Rn1 and so as to satisfy the constraints and minimize total expected cost, where σ is a probability measure. The (basic) Kuhn–Tucker conditions are obtained in terms of conditions on the existence of saddle points of a Lagrangian associated with the stochastic program. We also give an interpretation of these results in terms of equilibrium theory with particular emphasis on a nonstandard price system associated with the restriction that the (first stage) decision x1 must be chosen independent of the random elements of the problem.  相似文献   

7.
In contrast to a posterior analysis given a particular sampling model, posterior model probabilities in the context of model uncertainty are typically rather sensitive to the specification of the prior. In particular, ‘diffuse’ priors on model-specific parameters can lead to quite unexpected consequences. Here we focus on the practically relevant situation where we need to entertain a (large) number of sampling models and we have (or wish to use) little or no subjective prior information. We aim at providing an ‘automatic’ or ‘benchmark’ prior structure that can be used in such cases. We focus on the normal linear regression model with uncertainty in the choice of regressors. We propose a partly non-informative prior structure related to a natural conjugate g-prior specification, where the amount of subjective information requested from the user is limited to the choice of a single scalar hyperparameter g0j. The consequences of different choices for g0j are examined. We investigate theoretical properties, such as consistency of the implied Bayesian procedure. Links with classical information criteria are provided. More importantly, we examine the finite sample implications of several choices of g0j in a simulation study. The use of the MC3 algorithm of Madigan and York (Int. Stat. Rev. 63 (1995) 215), combined with efficient coding in Fortran, makes it feasible to conduct large simulations. In addition to posterior criteria, we shall also compare the predictive performance of different priors. A classic example concerning the economics of crime will also be provided and contrasted with results in the literature. The main findings of the paper will lead us to propose a ‘benchmark’ prior specification in a linear regression context with model uncertainty.  相似文献   

8.
This paper uses an aggregate modelling approach to assess the impacts of a redistribution of the taxes and duties that currently exist on crude oil and refined petroleum products on the Philippine economy. The approach used in the analysis consists of a general equilibrium model composed of fourteen producing sectors, fifteen consuming sectors, three household categories classified by income and a government. The effects of replacing the taxes and duties on crude oil and refined petroleum products with a more broad based tax on manufacturing and service sectors output on prices and quantities are examined. The results are revealing. For example, the consequences of redistributing the tax burden away from petroleum products to the manufacturing and service sectors of the Philippine economy will be an increase in output by all producing sectors of about 3.5 percent or about 2.4 hundred billion Philippine pesos, a rise in the consumption of goods and services by about 6.1 percent or 1.6 hundred billion Philippine pesos, a rise in total utility by 6.9 or 1.9 hundred billion Philippine pesos, and virtually no change in tax revenue for the government. When subjected to a sensitivity analysis, the results are reasonably robust with regard to the assumption of the values of the substitution elasticities. That is, while the model's equilibrium values do vary in response to different assumptions of the values of these elasticities, the fluctuations are not so enormous to suggest that the model is unrealistically sensitive to these parameters.Notation Y j Total production in sectorj (j=1, 2, ..., 14) - CD j Consumer demand for productj - GE j Government endowment of productj - UM j Imports of productj - LRASjl RAS balanced input-output intermediate demands - GD j Government demand for productj - INV j Investment in sectorj - UX j Exports of productj - SL c Supply of labor by householdc (c=1, 2, 3) - SK c Supply of capital by householdc - SD c Supply of land by householdc - DL j Demand for labor in the industryj - DK j Demand for capital in the industryj - DD j Demand for land in industryj - GDL Government demand for labor - GDD Government demand for land - TL j Tax on labor in industryj - TK j Tax on capital in industryj - TD j Tax on land in industryj - GCE i Consumer demand for consumer producti (i=1, 2, ..., 15) - Z ji A 14×15 transformation matrix - RCS ic RAS balanced matrix of each household's demand for each consumer good - TC j Excise tax on consumer goodj - TRN c Transfer payment to householdc - PIT c Personal income tax payment for householdc - TAU c Marginal income tax rate for householdc - SAV c Savings in householdc - GC c Gross consumption of householdc - ZTA Consumption plus leisure coefficient - TE Total government endowments - EM j Demand elasticity of export demand - FE j Endowment/demand sector of adjusted elasticity of export demand - GSK j Government endowment of capital in industryj - GDK j Government demand for capital in industryj - GTL Government wage taxes on its own employees - TXO j Government output tax on industryj - TC c Consumption taxes on householdc - CG c Total government consumption by householdc - SAV c Total savings by householdc - INV j Total investment by industryj The views expressed are those of the authors and do not necessarily represent the policies of the organizations with which they are affiliated. They would like to thank Wildrido Cruz of the World Bank and Climenta Habido of the Philippine government for help in acquiring the requisite data to calibrate the model used in the analysis. They would also like to thank an anonymous referee for helpful suggestions.  相似文献   

9.
Summary SupposeX is a non-negative random variable with an absolutely continuous (with respect to Lebesgue measure) distribution functionF (x) and the corresponding probability density functionf(x). LetX 1,X 2,...,X n be a random sample of sizen fromF andX i,n is thei-th smallest order statistics. We define thej-th order gapg i,j(n) asg i,j(n)=X i+j,n–Xi,n 1i<n, 1nn–i. In this paper a characterization of the exponential distribution is given by considering a distribution property ofg i,j(n).  相似文献   

10.
Let be an interval order on a topological space (X, τ), and let x ˜* y if and only if [y z x z], and x ˜** y if and only if [z x z y]. Then ˜* and ˜** are complete preorders. In the particular case when is a semiorder, let x ˜0 y if and only if x ˜* y and x ˜** y. Then ˜0 is a complete preorder, too. We present sufficient conditions for the existence of continuous utility functions representing ˜*, ˜** and ˜0, by using the notion of strong separability of a preference relation, which was introduced by Chateauneuf (Journal of Mathematical Economics, 1987, 16, 139–146). Finally, we discuss the existence of a pair of continuous functions u, υ representing a strongly separable interval order on a measurable topological space (X, τ, μ, ).  相似文献   

11.
T.W. Epps 《Metrika》2005,62(1):99-114
A class of procedures is presented for using random samples to test the fit of location-scale families—distributions F(·;θ1,θ2) such that Z=(Xθ1)/θ2 has distribution Working with empirically standardized data, the test statistic is a measure of distance between the empirical characteristic function, and the c.f. of Z under the null hypothesis, ϕ0(t). The closed-form test statistic is derived by integrating over the product of a weight function times Using as weight function for each location-scale family the squared modulus of ϕ0 itself presents a unified test procedure. Included as special cases are well-known tests for normal and Cauchy laws. Small-sample powers are compared with those of Anderson-Darling tests for each of seven univariate location-scale families.  相似文献   

12.
In the present paper families of truncated distributions with a Lebesgue density forx=(x 1,...,x n ) ε ℝ n are considered, wheref 0:ℝ → (0, ∞) is a known continuous function andC n (ϑ) denotes a normalization constant. The unknown truncation parameterϑ which is assumed to belong to a bounded parameter intervalΘ=[0,d] is to be estimated under a convex loss function. It is studied whether a two point prior and a corresponding Bayes estimator form a saddle point when the parameter interval is sufficiently small.  相似文献   

13.
R. M. Sekkappan 《Metrika》1981,28(1):123-132
Summary In this paper we obtain optimum allocation formula in stratified sampling from a finite population withk characteristics under study using the superpopulation approach put forth byEricson [1969a]. Allocation at the second phase is also considered using information obtained from the first phase. Two different approaches are employed: a Bayesian posterior analysis and a Bayesian preposterior analysis. It is also shown that our allocation formulae for the second phase observations include the results ofMohd. Zubair Khan [1976] andDraper/Guttman [1968a] as special cases when the unknown characteristicX ij possessed by the (i, j)-th element is scalar valued and the stratum sizes are large.  相似文献   

14.
In a paper byMathai/Saxena [1968, 21–39], the present authors found some entries with error and others with lack of precision. Recently,Conde/Kalla [1979] have tabulated2 F 1 (a, b; c; x) fora=0.5 (0.5) 5.0,b=0.5 (0.5) 5.0,c=0.5 (0.5) 12 andx=–2.50 (0.05) 0.95. The present note explains the method of computation and checks applied, Wronskians, continuation formulae, special cases etc. to insure the stated accuracy.  相似文献   

15.
Prof. Dr. T. Royen 《Metrika》1991,38(1):299-315
Summary A new representation for the characteristic function of the joint distribution of the Mahalanobis distances betweenk independentN(μ, Σ)-distributed points is given. Especially fork=3 the corresponding distribution function is obtained as a special case of multivariate gamma distributions whose accompanying normal distribution has a positive semidefinite correlation matrix with correlationsϱ ij=−a i a j. These gamma distribution functions are given here by one-dimensional parameter integrals. With some further trivariate gamma distributions third order Bonferroni inequalities are derived for the upper tails of the distribution function of the multivariate range ofk independentN(μ, I)-distributed points. From these inequalities very accurate (conservative) approximations to upperα-level bounds can also be computed for studentized multivariate ranges.  相似文献   

16.
In this paper we investigate the number of coalitions that block a given non-competitive allocation. In an atomless economy with a finite number of types we identify coalition with its profile. Considering profiles π that represent coalitions with the same proportions of types as in the whole society, we prove that there is a ball Bπ with π as its center so that ‘almost half’ of the profiles in Bπ are blocking. This result is an analogous result to that of Mas-Colell (1978) who dealt with large finite markets.  相似文献   

17.
Let P={F,G,…} be the set of probability distribution functions on [0,b]. For each αε[1, ∞), FαG means that ∫xo(xyα−1dF(y)∫xo(xy)α−1dG(y) for all xε[0, b], and F>αG means that FαG and FG. Each α is reflexive and transitive and each>α is asymmetric and transitive. Both α and>α increase as α increases but their limits are not complete. A class Uα of utility functions is defined to give F>αG iffudF>∫udG for all uεUα. These classes decrease as α increases, and their limit is empty. Similar decreasing classes are defined for each α, and their limit is essentially the constant functions on (0, b].  相似文献   

18.
We consider the normalized least squares estimator of the parameter in a nearly integrated first-order autoregressive model with dependent errors. In a first step we consider its asymptotic distribution as well as asymptotic expansion up to order Op(T−1). We derive a limiting moment generating function which enables us to calculate various distributional quantities by numerical integration. A simulation study is performed to assess the adequacy of the asymptotic distribution when the errors are correlated. We focus our attention on two leading cases: MA(1) errors and AR(1) errors. The asymptotic approximations are shown to be inadequate as the MA root gets close to −1 and as the AR root approaches either −1 or 1. Our theoretical analysis helps to explain and understand the simulation results of Schwert (1989) and DeJong, Nankervis, Savin, and Whiteman (1992) concerning the size and power of Phillips and Perron's (1988) unit root test. A companion paper, Nabeya and Perron (1994), presents alternative asymptotic frameworks in the cases where the usual asymptotic distribution fails to provide an adequate approximation to the finite-sample distribution.  相似文献   

19.
This paper investigates the case of a monopolist selling two distinct goods to a group of m traders who are characterized by their reservation prices, which are drawn independently from uniform distributions over the intervals [ 0, R1] and [ 0, R2] . Closed‐form solutions are derived for optimal prices, quantities, profits, and consumers' surplus under situations of separate sales, pure bundling, and mixed bundling. This allows a clear comparison of the price, output, and welfare effects of various forms of bundling. We further investigate situations of positive marginal cost, positive and negative correlation of reservation values, and substitutes and complements.  相似文献   

20.
Structural instability of the core   总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1  
Let σ be a q-rule, where any coalition of size q, from the society of size n, is decisive. Let w(n,q)= 2q-n+1 and let W be a smooth ‘policy space’ of dimension w. Let U(W)N be the space of all smooth profiles on W, endowed with the Whitney topology. It is shown that there exists an ‘instability dimension’ w*(σ) with 2w*(σ)w(n,q) such that:
1. (i) if ww*(σ), and W has no boundary, then the core of σ is empty for a dense set of profiles in U(W)N (i.e., almost always),
2. (ii) if ww*(σ)+1, and W has a boundary, then the core of σ is empty, almost always,
3. (iii) if ww*(σ)+1 then the cycle set is dense in W, almost always,
4. (iv) if ww*(σ)+2 then the cycle set is also path connected, almost always.
The method of proof is first of all to show that if a point belongs to the core, then certain generalized symmetry conditions in terms of ‘pivotal’ coalitions of size 2qn must be satisfied. Secondly, it is shown that these symmetry conditions can almost never be satisfied when either W has empty boundary and is of dimension w(n,q) or when W has non-empty boundary and is of dimension w(n,q)+1.  相似文献   

设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号