共查询到20条相似文献,搜索用时 15 毫秒
1.
This paper examines evolutionary equilibrium selection in bargaining models. We show that random best-response and continuous best-response learning dynamics give rise to (different) simple sufficient conditions for identifying outcomes as stochastically stable. This allows us to characterize the implications of these dynamics in simple bargaining games. 相似文献
2.
Since the early 1970s, the literature examining the court system has placed much emphasis on the importance of the jury size and voting rule when analyzing the jury decision-making process. In addition, researchers have also used deductive reasoning to theoretically determine the cost-minimizing jury size and voting rule with regards to Type I and Type II errors. In this paper, we take this analysis one step further by empirically estimating the cost-minimizing jury size and voting rule in civil jury trials. 相似文献
3.
Hankyoung Sung 《Experimental Economics》2007,10(2):195-196
This dissertation experimentally analyzes the outcomes of multilateral legislative bargaining games in the presence of a veto
player.
The first essay examines veto power—the right of an agent to unilaterally block decisions but without the ability to unilaterally
secure his/her preferred outcome. Using Winter’s (1996) theoretical framework, I consider two cases: urgent committees where
the total amount of money to be distributed shrinks by 50% if proposals do not pass and non-urgent committees where the total
amount of money shrinks by 5% if proposals do not pass. Committees with a veto player take longer to reach decisions (are
less efficient) than without a veto player and veto players proposals generate less consensus then non-veto players proposals,
outcomes on which the theory is silent. In addition, veto power in conjunction with proposer power generates excessive power
for the veto player. This suggests that limiting veto players’ proposer rights (e.g., limiting their ability to chair committees)
would go a long way to curbing their power, a major concern in committees in which one or more players has veto power. Finally,
non-veto players show substantially more willingness to compromise than veto players, with players in the control game somewhere
in between. I relate the results to the theoretical literature on the impact of veto power as well as concerns about the impact
of veto power in real-life committees.
The second essay discusses in detail the voting patterns in the veto and control games reported in the first essay. The empirical
cumulative density functions of shares veto players accepted first degree stochastically dominates that of shares for the
controls and the empirical cdfs of shares the controls accepted first degree stochastically dominate that of shares for non-veto
players. Random effect probits support this conclusion as well. In addition, regressions imply favorable treatment of voting
and proposing between non-veto players which, however, does not result in larger shares in the end. Coalition partners consistently
demand more than the stationary subgame perfect Nash equilibrium share except for veto players in non-urgent committees.
JEL Classification C7, D7, C78, D72
Dissertation Committee:
John H. Kagel, Advisor
Massimo Morelli
Alan Wiseman
Stephen Cosslett 相似文献
4.
We consider a non-cooperative multilateral bargaining game and study an action-dependent bargaining protocol, that is, the probability with which a player becomes the proposer in a round of bargaining depends on the identity of the player who previously rejected. An important example is the frequently studied rejector-becomes-proposer protocol. We focus on subgame perfect equilibria in stationary strategies which are shown to exist and to be efficient. Equilibrium proposals do not depend on the probability to propose conditional on the rejection by another player. We consider the limit, as the bargaining friction vanishes. In case no player has a positive probability to propose conditional on his rejection, each player receives his utopia payoff conditional on being recognized. Otherwise, equilibrium proposals of all players converge to a weighted Nash bargaining solution, where the weights are determined by the probability to propose conditional on one's own rejection. 相似文献
5.
Mele FE 《Medical economics》2000,77(8):112, 118-120, 123
6.
H Moulin 《Journal of Economic Theory》1984,33(1):32-45
The bargaining game is proposed where the agents bid fractions of dictatorship that are used by all non-winners of the auction to threaten acceptance of the winner's proposal. That procedure non-cooperatively implements the Kalai-Smorodinsky bargaining solution. 相似文献
7.
Suppose that a firm has several owners and that the future is uncertain in the sense that one out of many different states of nature will realize tomorrow. An owner’s time preference and risk attitude will determine the importance he places on payoffs in the different states. It is a well-known problem in the literature that under incomplete asset markets, a conflict about the firm’s objective function tends to arise among its owners. In this paper, we take a new approach to this problem, which is based on non-cooperative bargaining. The owners of the firm play a bargaining game in order to choose the firm’s production plan and a scheme of transfers which are payable before the uncertainty about the future state of nature is resolved. We analyze the resulting firm decision in the limit of subgame-perfect equilibria in stationary strategies. Given the distribution of bargaining power, we obtain a unique prediction for a production plan and a transfer scheme. When markets are complete, the production plan chosen corresponds to the profit-maximizing production plan as in the Arrow–Debreu model. Contrary to that model, owners typically do use transfers to redistribute profits. When markets are incomplete, the production plan chosen is almost always different from the one in a transfer-free Drèze (pseudo-)equilibrium and again owners use transfers to redistribute profits. Nevertheless, our results do support the Drèze criterion as the appropriate objective function of the firm. 相似文献
8.
Chen-Ying Huang 《Economic Theory》2002,20(2):401-412
Summary. We present a game in which n persons split a cake, where a distinction between conditional and unconditional offers is made. This distinction sheds light
on the contrasting results obtained in the previous literature of multilateral bargaining. By allowing the proposer to make
both conditional and unconditional offers, we show that the game has a unique subgame perfect Nash equilibrium outcome.
Received: March 14, 2000; revised version: March 13, 2001 相似文献
9.
Summary. This paper provides an axiomatic characterization of a family of so-called efficient maxmin solutions which can be seen as
generalizations of the Kalai-Smorodinsky solution to nonconvex n-person bargaining problems. Moreover, it is shown that even though there are several efficient maxmin solutions for some
bargaining problems, there is typically a unique efficient maxmin solution.
Received: February 15, 2001; revised version: November 14, 2001 相似文献
10.
Walter Trockel 《Economic Theory》2005,25(1):255-263
Summary. Core equivalence and shrinking of the core results are well known for economies. The present paper establishes counterparts for bargaining economies, a specific class of production economies (finite and infinite) representing standard two-person bargaining games and their continuum counterparts as coalition production economies. Thereby we get core equivalence of the Nash solution. The results reconfirm the Walrasian approach to Nash bargaining of Trockel (1996). Moreover we establish the same speed of convergence as is known from Debreu (1975) and Grodal (1975) for replicated pure exchange economies and for regular purely competitive sequences of economies, respectively.Received: 13 June 2003, Revised: 13 January 2004, JEL Classification Numbers:
C71, C78, D51.This article is dedicated to Birgit Grodal, a friend since 30 years.Financial support of the DFG under grant #444 USA 111/2/03 is gratefully acknowledged. 相似文献
11.
Hans Peters 《Economics Letters》1985,17(3):219-222
Necessary and sufficient conditions are given under which a decision maker's von Neumann-Morgenstern utility function on the Cartesian product of two prospect spaces can be expressed as a sum of coordinate utility functions, assuming that all preferences are given. A main motivation for this result is an application in axiomatic bargaining theory. 相似文献
12.
This note reexamines the connection between the asymmetric Nash bargaining solution and the equilibria of strategic bargaining games. A first example shows non-convergence to the asymmetric Nash bargaining solution. A second example demonstrates the possibility of multiple limits. 相似文献
13.
14.
《Economics Letters》1986,21(2):131-134
Two axioms concerning changes in the conflict point are introduced. A sufficient condition for a solution function to satisfy these axioms is that it satisfies the relatively weak adding requirement of Thomson-Myerson (1980). 相似文献
15.
Eiichi Miyagawa 《Games and Economic Behavior》2002,41(2):14
We study house allocation problems introduced by L. Shapley and H. Scarf (1974, J. Math. Econ.1, 23–28). We prove that a mechanism (a social choice function) is individually rational, anonymous, strategy-proof, and nonbossy (but not necessarily Pareto efficient) if and only if it is either the core mechanism or the no-trade mechanism, where the no-trade mechanism is the one that selects the initial allocation for each profile of preferences. This result confirms the intuition that even if we are willing to accept inefficiency, there exists no interesting strategy-proof mechanism other than the core mechanism. Journal of Economic Literature Classification Numbers: C71, C78, D71, D78, D89. 相似文献
16.
Michael Maschler 《Journal of Economic Theory》1976,13(2):184-192
An example of a market game is described for which the bargaining set seems to be intuitively more acceptable than the (nonempty) core. It also yields more insight into the nature of the competition that may exist among the traders. 相似文献
17.
In this paper we study how bargainers impact on markets in which firms set a list price to sell to those consumers who take prices as given. The list price acts as an outside option for the bargainers, so the higher the list price, the more the firms can extract from bargainers. We find that an increase in the proportion of consumers seeking to bargain can lower consumer surplus overall, even though new bargainers receive a lower price. The reason is that the list price for those who do not bargain and the bargained prices for those who were already bargaining rise: sellers have a greater incentive to make the bargainers’ outside option less attractive, reducing the incentive to compete for price takers. Competition Authority exhortations to bargain can therefore be misplaced. We also consider the implications for optimal seller bargaining. 相似文献
18.
Summary. In this paper the alternating offer model with an exogenous risk of breakdown is taken to explicitly model the bargaining process underlying the variable threat game (Nash, Econometrica, 1953). A modified version of the variable threat game without commitment is also analysed within a dynamic context. The limit set of subgame perfect equilibria is characterized in both dynamic versions. The analysis gives rise to different results than in the two standard models. By making additional assumptions the original results can be regained, indicating that these are implicitly present in the standard analysis.Received: August 29, 1995; revised version: November 11, 1996This revised version was published online in February 2005 with corrections to the cover date. 相似文献
19.
We study multilateral bargaining games where agents disagree over their bargaining power. We show that if agents are extremely optimistic, there may be costly delays in an arbitrarily long finite game but if optimism is moderate, all sufficiently long games end in immediate agreement. We show that the game with extreme optimism is highly unstable in the finite-horizon, and we examine the ramifications of this instability on the infinite-horizon problem. Finally, we consider other voting rules, and show that the majority-rule may be more efficient than the unanimity rule when agents are optimistic. 相似文献
20.
Mark Gradstein 《European Economic Review》2004,48(5):983-999
In recent decades, the issues of federalism and political integration have gained prominence in public debate as well as in the academic realm. A frequently made point is that allowing free secession may protect the minority's interests, thus providing it with an incentive to enter the federation. This paper explicitly considers the political process in the federation arguing that the option to secede may distort the political choices made by the individual regions to improve their bargaining positions. As a result, the allocation of resources in the federation could well end up being inefficient and unattractive for the minority region. In contrast, limiting the secession possibilities by requiring the consent of a majority of voters through a regional referendum, rather than leaving it to the discretion of the legislature, restores efficiency. 相似文献