首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
相似文献
 共查询到20条相似文献,搜索用时 453 毫秒
1.
Differences between U.S. and Canadian marketing policies in malting barley have been identified as potential sources of trade distortions. Most important are issues related to quality control, yield differentials between feed and malting varieties, and differences in handling costs. This study analyzes effects of changes in selected marketing policies on trade flows and prices in the North American malting barley sector using a mathematical programming model. Simulation results illustrate impacts of relaxed variety release requirements, increased selection rates for malting barley, reduced Canadian handling costs and the effect of increased Canadian exports of malting barley to offshore markets. The results quantify effects of these strategic issues on both the United States and Canadian barley sectors.  相似文献   

2.
Major changes have been occurring in agricultural policies affecting world malt and malting barley production and trade. This paper analyzes effects of these changes on international trade and competition. A spatially disaggregated linear programing model of the world malt and malting barley sector is constructed and used to analyze effects of changes in European Union supply, European Union restitutions, the U.S. Export Enhancement Program subsidy regime, and import tariffs on malt and malting barley. Policy changes are found to generate substantial changes in trade flows and competitiveness between producing and exporting regions.  相似文献   

3.
One of the trade policy issues identified by U.S. interests, including grower groups, traders and policy makers, is price transparency. This has been a point of contention between the United States and Canada as well as other exporting countries with state trading enterprises (STEs). The transparency problem generally refers to the inability to observe terms of trade (including price, quality, credit, etc.)offered by STEs, and the potential strategic advantage this provides in bidding competition. A game theory model of import tendering is developed in this paper to examine the effects of information asymmetry among rivals. Several stylized examples are used to illustrate aspects of competition and to analyze effects on bidding strategies. Results indicate that:
  • Less uncertainty among rivals reduces equilibrium bids and prices.

      相似文献   

4.
The Coors Brewing Company owns a single-site, integrated malting facility and brewery in Golden, Colorado; a second brewery in Memphis, Tennessee; and a mixing facility in Elkton, Virginia. Coors operates a research and development program that breeds barley varieties suitable for malting at the Golden site. Coors contracts with 900 growers in Colorado, Idaho, Montana, and Wyoming for approximately 160,000 acres of malting barley. This case study is designed for senior- and graduate-level courses in agribusiness management. The case relates three theories of vertical coordination to Coors' decision to contract 100% of its malting barley requirements.  相似文献   

5.
A chance constrained programming model is developed to assist Queensland barley growers make varietal and agronomic decisions in the face of changing product demands and volatile production conditions. Unsuitable or overlooked in many risk programming applications, the chance constrained programming approach nonetheless aptly captures the single-stage decision problem faced by barley growers of whether to plant lower-yielding but potentially higher-priced malting varieties, given a particular expectation of meeting malting grade standards. Different expectations greatly affect the optimal mix of malting and feed barley activities. The analysis highlights the suitability of chance constrained programming to this specific class of farm decision problem.  相似文献   

6.
Export state trading enterprises (STEs) play an important role in global agricultural trade. STE behavior has significant implications for world food markets, irrespective of whether or not these markets are inherently competitive. Previous literature has suggested that STEs have market power and can earn oligopolistic rents. We find there is no compelling empirical evidence to support this argument. However, we show the cross-commodity effects of export STEs can disrupt competitive world markets, through offering an implicit export subsidy to a downstream industry.  相似文献   

7.
8.
Under a continental barley marketing system, the Canadian Wheat Board would no longer be the only exporter of barley to the United States. Even though the volume of malting barley exports to the United States would increase, the historic price premium in both Canada and the United States would drop sufficiently to lower total revenue to malting barley producers. The United States' Export Enhancement Program allows the Canadian Wheat Board to sell feed barley at premium prices in some markets, including the United States. Under some conditions the continental barley market would adversely affect optimal trade flows and reduce revenue for feed barley producers. The potential to offset these losses in revenue by reducing grain-handling charges or by growing higher-yielding feed varieties appears to be very limited. Dans un système de marché continental de l'brge, la Commission canadienne du blé ne serait plus le seul exportateur d'orge vers les Etats-Unis. Même si Ie volume des exportations d'orge de malterie augmentait, la prime dont a longtemps bénéficié cette catégorie d'orge, tant au Canada qu'aux Etats-Unis, tomberait suffisamment pour abaisser les recettes totales des producteurs. Par ailleurs, le Programme américain de stimulation des exportations (EEP) autorise actuellement la CCB à vendre son orge fourragère à prime sur certains marchés, dont les Etats-his. Dans certaines circonstances, le marché continental de l'orge aurait un effet négatif sur les courants d'échange et réduirait les recettes des producteurs de ce type d'orge. Les possibilités de compenser ces pertes de revenu parune compression des frais de manutention et de stockage ou par la mise en service de variétés fourragères à rendement plus élevé paraissent très restreintes.  相似文献   

9.
The Australian Wheat Board (AWB) and Canadian Wheat Board (CWB) have attracted attention recently because they are two of the largest state trading enterprises (STEs) engaged in agricultural trade. They have traditionally been viewed as nearly sister agencies. Among major STEs in the world market, these two agencies historically had similar characteristics including: price pooling, cost pooling, export sales monopolies, monopoly powers within domestic markets, grain quality control, and government underwriting of initial producer prices and export credit. However, during the past 6 years, similarities between the AWB and CWB have begun to diverge and the importance of their differences is becoming increasingly apparent. This paper identifies major emerging differences between the AWB and CWB and explores potential explanations (hypotheses) for these dissimilarities. A major point is that reforms in institutional design and legislative changes have given rise to emerging differences in key aspects of the marketing systems and performance.  相似文献   

10.
Article XVII of the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade is the main World Trade Organization (WTO) vehicle for regulating trade-distorting policies implemented through state trading enterprises (STEs). The effectiveness of Article XVII depends on how WTO dispute panels and the Appellate Body interpret the provisions. This study examines the 2003 WTO trade dispute case between the United States and Canada over Canadian grain imports and the practices of the Canadian Wheat Board, an export STE. We conclude that the WTO panel and Appellate Body rationales for their findings demonstrate that Article XVII needs substantial revision for the WTO to discipline STE trade-distorting practices.  相似文献   

11.
This study views multilateral trade negotiations as a strategic game among nations or regions, including taxpayer, consumer, and producer components. Payoffs are calculated from an intermediate-run international trade model initialized with 1989 data. For the public at large, the Nash equilibrium and socially optimal outcome is liberalization of trade – unilateral or multilateral. Maintenance of the status quo of market distortions costing the world billions of dollars each year is rational only if producer payoffs are sovereign so that strategies optimal for producers are considered optimal for nations. Remedial policies are discussed, including opportunities for economic education, political system reform, and less incentives for producers to scuttle multilateral trade negotiations.  相似文献   

12.
[目的]基于多视角开展"一带一路"沿线国家群组划分,提出"一带一路"农业国际合作重要战略节点国家,并探讨新冠肺炎疫情对重要战略节点国家与我国农业国际合作的影响,对进一步促进我国与"一带一路"沿线国家全面农业国际合作,打破农业国际合作瓶颈具有重要意义。[方法]文章通过地理位置、地缘政治、资源禀赋、农产品贸易等多个角度,结合引力模型和聚类分析法,对"一带一路"农业国际合作的重要战略节点国家进行分析。并从农产品贸易和投资两个角度探讨新冠肺炎疫情对重要战略节点国家和我国农业国际合作的影响。[结果]在"一带一路"沿线国家中,我国农业合作的重要战略节点国家按重要性划分为两个层次,第一层次为俄罗斯、哈萨克斯坦、波兰、缅甸、越南、泰国、巴基斯坦、埃及、印度尼西亚和马来西亚;第二层次为希腊、柬埔寨和老挝。新冠肺炎疫情对重要战略节点国家和我国的农业贸易、投资合作造成了不可忽略的影响。[结论]为进一步加强我国与"一带一路"重要战略节点国家农业国际合作,应在十九大提出的"六个坚持"理念指引下,从基础设施建设、资源禀赋、部门协调、共同抗疫四个方面,继续深化"一带一路"农业国际合作。  相似文献   

13.
目的 面对日益严峻复杂的国际经济政治环境,理清全球农产品贸易格局演变的特征及趋势,对于及时应对国际农产品市场风险、提高国际循环利用能力具有重要意义。方法 基于社会网络分析法,利用1996—2021年世界农产品贸易数据,文章从总体—行业—加工程度3个维度分别构建了全球农产品贸易网络,定量分析了全球农产品贸易网络的格局演化及重要节点特征。结果 (1)各国间农产品贸易关联日益加深,处于核心地位的国家数量显著增加,以美国为代表的单中心主导地位被削弱,但由少数国家主导全球农产品贸易的情形并未改变。(2)中国在全球农产品贸易网络中地位显著提升,点度中心度和接近中心度均位于前列,但中介中心度处于较低水平,说明中国对全球农业资源和市场的掌控能力依然不足。(3)各国在不同细分行业中的地位呈现明显的异质性,大多数国家的进口集中于少数贸易伙伴的少数产品,加工贸易逐渐成为全球农产品贸易的主流,发展高附加值农产品贸易成为各国农业贸易长远发展的战略选择。结论 为此,应持续优化农产品贸易布局,拓展与亚洲、拉美、非洲等新兴市场的贸易,不断提升农业全球价值链地位。  相似文献   

14.
The long expected new enlargement of the Community to include Spain and Portugal will undoubtedly affect existing trade arrangements of the EEC with the south and south-eastern countries of the Mediterranean basin. After examining the economic, political and strategic importance of the Mediterranean area to the Community, the paper suggests two approaches to reforming and strengthening the external Mediterranean policy of EEC-12: first, a short-term piecemeal approach to protect the sensitive areas of Mediterranean export trade, and second, a longer-term policy concept that will gradually lead to a new division of labour between the EEC and its Mediterranean trade partners.  相似文献   

15.
加强农业国际合作开发是中国特色农业现代化道路的重要组成部分,东南亚与我国合作开发地缘优势明显,是我国农业海外合作开发的重要首选区域。在国家"一带一路"的全球战略格局指导下,通过区域比较优势分析等方法,立足我国对粮食等大宗战略农产品的发展需求、东南亚各国的农业资源禀赋与合作意向,从提升我国农业国际竞争力和话语权的高度,系统谋划了东南亚地区农业合作开发的战略重点领域,确定以稻谷、天然橡胶、油棕榈、木薯、甘蔗和林业六大行业为合作重点,以提升原料掌控权和贸易话语权为关键环节,根据东南亚重要交通物流通道、资源禀赋和产业基础的区域差异,提出"三线两区"的合作开发总体布局。围绕各种合作有力推进,提出设立专项基金、加强金融支持、提升政府服务等政策建议保障,为我国政府与企业在东南亚地区长远战略合作的顶层设计提供重要依据和支撑。  相似文献   

16.
In this article, we investigate whether the Brazilian notifications to the TBT and SPS agreements are characterized as retaliation or as cooperation in international agricultural trade in the period 1996–2008. A Generalized Method of Moments (GMM) model is used to estimate game models of bilateral trade between Brazil and its major partners (United States, European Union, and Japan). From the viewpoint of strategic games, the results suggest that the Brazilian notifications are forms of retaliation against the United States, and, regarding the European Union, the best result for Brazil was conciliation. On the other hand, if the results are interpreted as equilibria of bargaining games, they suggest that Brazil has great bargaining power in trade with the United States and that cooperation characterized agricultural trade between Brazil and the European Union in the period analyzed. In the case of agricultural trade between Brazil and Japan, only Japan has characteristics of a country with significant bargaining power.  相似文献   

17.
In early 2020, China, Australia's top export market, unilaterally imposed trade restrictions on Australian barley, beef, coal, cotton, timber, copper and wine. However, convincing evidence regarding the effects of such trade restrictions on firms is scarce. Leveraging data on daily stock returns from 20 listed Australian and 32 listed Chinese firms that produce the restricted commodities, we provide the first systematic analysis of the firm-level economic impacts of China's trade restrictions on Australian and Chinese firms. We find significant adverse effects on Australian firms' stock returns, leading to almost 20% loss within 10 trading days; however, most firms' stock returns immediately rebounded. In contrast, Chinese firms usually saw significant positive stock returns, leading to almost 30% gains, and the positive abnormal returns continuously increased within 10 trading days. Media coverage and trade dependence substantially impact Australian and Chinese firms' stock returns—industries with stronger trade dependence on China saw greater losses in Australian firms' stock returns. Our results suggest that trade reallocation and deflection are two effective mitigation mechanisms for Australian exporters facing China's trade restrictions.  相似文献   

18.
我国石油贸易现状和对策研究   总被引:3,自引:0,他引:3  
文章简述了中国石油对外贸易的发展 ;对中国石油对外贸易的方式、结构及其变化 ,以及中国原油进口来源等进行了分析 ;指出了中国石油贸易存在的主要问题。在此基础上提出中国石油对外贸易战略对策 :一是提高国内供给能力 ,适当控制国内需求 ;二是根据中国石油供需情况适度进口 ;三是建立以中东原油为主的多元进口原油格局。  相似文献   

19.
On I August 1993, the Canadian government extended the dual feed barley market to all of North America and established a similar marketing system for malting barley. The 1993 policy reform removed the Canadian Wheat Board's (limited) ability to set monopoly prices. While the loss of the board's domestic monopoly power was negative for farmers, there were offsetting positive impacts. The new policy will lead to economic gains for farmers due to improved price signals and competitive discipline in grain handling. The author concludes that the gains to farmers from a move to a single North American market far ourneigh any associated losses. Le 1er août 1993, le gouvernement canadien étendait le système de double marché de l'brge fourragère a toute l'Amérique du Nord et instaurait un régime semblable pour l'orge de brasserie. La réforme de 1993 retirait à la Commission canadienne du blé son quasi-monopole sur l'établissement des prix. Bien que cette perte de monopole ait eu des effets négatifs pour les agriculteurs, elle a eu certaines incidences positives. La nouvelle politique apportera aux agriculteurs des gains économiques en leur envoyant des signalcx plus clairs sur les prix du marché, et aussi par l'instauration d'une discipline plus concurrentielle du réseau de manutention des céréales. L'auteur estime que les avantages pour les agriculteurs du passage à un marché unique pour l'Amérique du Nord compenseront largement les penes corollaires éventuelles que peuvent en découler.  相似文献   

20.
A two-stage budgeting procedure is employed to analyze the Japanese import demand for barley and the allocation of Japanese barley imports between North America (Canada and the United States) and Australia. It is found that the import demand for barley is price inelastic and that corn is a substitute for barley. Japanese barley imports are also influenced by size of the cattle herd and the number of cattle slaughtered. Price competition plays a significant role in import allocation, and budget shares of the two suppliers are proportional to total import expenditure. Since April 1991, import quotas and the involvement of the Livestock Industry Promotion Corporation (a quasi-government agency) in the Japanese beef trade have been replaced with higher tariffs and direct negotiations between traders. These changes promise easier access to the Japanese beef market and have been predicted to exert adverse impacts on the Japanese cattle industry. Different responses of the Japanese cattle industry under trade liberalization are assumed and are combined with the estimated econometric models to forecast Japanese barley imports in total and by country of origin. The effect of a reduced price for North American barley is also investigated, since reduced total imports under trade liberalization may intensify price competition. Une procédure budgétaire en deux étapes permet d'analyser la demande d'orge à l'importation au Japon et l'allocation des importations japanaises d'orge entre l'Amérique du Nord (le Canada et les Etats-Unis) et l'Australie. Les résultats indiquent que la demande d'orge à l'importation est inélastique par rapport au prix et que le maïs est un substitut pour l'orge. Les importations japonaises d'orge sont aussi fonction de la taille du troupeau global au Japon et du nombre d'animaux abattus. La concurrence par les prix joue un rôle important dans l'allocation des importations entre les deux pays. De plus, les parts du budget allouées aux deux zones fournisseurs sont proportionnelles à la dépense total sur les importations. Depuis avril 1991, les quotas à l'importation et l'implication de la corporation para-étatique (Livestock Industry Promotion Corporation) dans le commerce japonais du boeuf ont été remplacés par des tarifs plus élevés et des négotiations directes entre les commercants du marché international. Ces modifications devraient faciliter l'accès au marché japonais du boeufet tel qu'attendu pourront avoir des effets néfastes sur le secteur bovin japonais. Plusieurs scénarios simulant la réponse de l'industrie bovine japonaise à la libéralisation des échanges sont proposés et sont utilisés en conjonction avec un modèle économétrique pour effectuer des prévisions du niveau total des importations d'orge au Japon ainsi que le pays d'origine de celles-ci. L'impact d'une réduction du prix de l'orge en Amérique du Nord est aussi considéré, puisqu'une réduction des importations totales suite à la libéralisation des échanges pourrait intensifier la concurrence par les prix.  相似文献   

设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号