首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
相似文献
 共查询到20条相似文献,搜索用时 46 毫秒
1.
一、合肥市物流业与制造业联动发展背景1.制造业发展背景。工业立市是合肥市国民经济社会发展的核心战略,近年来,通过大力发展工业经济,其汽车、装备制造、新材料、家电、电子信息及软件、生物医药等一个个产业集群正以几何方式聚集,合肥市已经  相似文献   

2.
作为安徽省省会城市的合肥,近些年其经济发展速度可以说是突飞猛进.而且合肥市在加快安徽省社会经济发展融入长三角的过程中也同样扮演着重要的角色.合肥市在推动全省社会经济发展及各方面建设中起了重要的引领和带头作用,尤其是在金融业发展过程中,为其他地级市的金融产业发展提供了许多可供参考的经验.针对合肥市区域金融中心建设现状的研究,可以帮助我们更加清晰的看到整个合肥市在金融产业发展中所延续的发展道路和模式.  相似文献   

3.
对合肥服务外包基地发展的调研与思考   总被引:7,自引:0,他引:7  
安徽省合肥市于2007年12月被国家商务部、信息产业部、科学技术部批准为"中国服务外包基地城市"。2008年7月至8月,笔者对加快合肥市服务外包基地发展进行了专题调研,先后调研了安徽省商务厅、合肥市外经贸局、合肥市高新技术开发区、合肥  相似文献   

4.
本文首先分析了合肥市旅游饭店业的发展现状,指出合肥市旅游饭店业在整个安徽省旅游业发展中的重要地位.在此基础上,从企业规模、经济效益与经济贡献、成本与费用三大方面构建了评价指标体系,运用主成分分析法和因子分析法对合肥市旅游饭店09年经营数据加以分析,从而对合肥市旅游饭店的发展现状进行了客观评价,对旅游饭店竞争力的提高有一定的指导作用.  相似文献   

5.
本文首先分析了合肥市旅游饭店业的发展现状,指出合肥市旅游饭店业在整个安徽省旅游业发展中的重要地位。在此基础上,从企业规模、经济效益与经济贡献、成本与费用三大方面构建了评价指标体系,运用主成分分析法和因子分析法对合肥市旅游饭店09年经营数据加以分析,从而对合肥市旅游饭店的发展现状进行了客观评价,对旅游饭店竞争力的提高有一定的指导作用。  相似文献   

6.
从对外贸易发展的规模、效益、潜力三个角度构建一个城市对外贸易发展的竞争力评价指标体系,采用主成分分析法,将合肥市的外贸发展竞争力与长三角区域内其他十四个城市进行比较。研究结果表明,合肥市对外贸易发展竞争力总得分在15个城市中排名第13位,外贸竞争力水平不高。对此为合肥市提高对外贸易水平提出相应的政策建议。  相似文献   

7.
本文通过对合肥市小额贷款公司经营现状的思考,探讨进一步提高合肥市小额贷款公司健康、可持续发展的思路及经验总结  相似文献   

8.
党的十九大做出我国经济已由高速增长阶段转向高质量发展阶段的重大判断,加快培育经济高质量发展新动能是合肥市目前重点推进的发展工程之一.本文根据界定的新时代合肥市经济高质量发展新动能的主要内容,构建测度合肥市经济高质量发展新动能水平的指标体系,搜集合肥市近十年的指标数据,借助熵权法合成出新动能指数,并基于各级新动能指数对合肥近十年的新动能发展水平进行分析评价,发现合肥市2010年至2019年新动能水平总体上稳中有升,其中供给侧动能发展势头强劲,结构转换动能稳步增长,需求侧动能增长较为缓慢且波动较大.最后综合上述分析结果,针对现阶段合肥市经济高质量发展和新动能培育的特点,提出若干切实可行的有助于合肥培育经济高质量发展新动能的对策建议:以创新挖掘引领新动能培育;以结构升级壮大新动能培育;以持续开放促进新动能培育;以协调发展布局新动能培育.  相似文献   

9.
合肥市"滨湖新区"的概念于20世纪90年代中后期提出,"十一五"规划正式将其落实到实施阶段,不但有创新的规划理念,而且有科学的功能定位以及长期的发展愿景。合肥市滨湖新区的推出具有客观历史必然性,也是合肥市实施跨越式发展战略的必然选择。整个新区项目成本小、发展快、标准高、理念创新,既坚持以人为本,又兼顾经济事业发展,对今后城市化过程中不断出现的城市新区的建设和发展有一定的参考价值。  相似文献   

10.
宫成 《经济师》2012,(10):200-202
在全球经济不景气的背景下,合肥市经济发展屡创佳绩,其生产总值增速连续7年居中部省会第一位。文章在应用库茨涅茨法则的基础上,计算合肥市三大产业的比较劳动生产率与劳动力构成、生产总值的摩尔变动值,探究产业结构变动速率与趋势,分析合肥市在"工业立市"战略下的产业发展、确立主导产业、承接产业转移等问题,并对产业结构的升级与优化给出相关建议,为今后合肥市经济发展方向提供参考。  相似文献   

11.
Rule of law, democracy, openness, and income   总被引:7,自引:0,他引:7  
We estimate the interrelationships among economic institutions, political institutions, openness, and income levels, using identification through heteroskedasticity (IH). We split our cross‐national dataset into two sub‐samples: (i) colonies versus non‐colonies; and (ii) continents aligned on an East–West versus those aligned on a North–South axis. We exploit the difference in the structural variances in these two sub‐samples to gain identification. We find that democracy and the rule of law are both good for economic performance, but the latter has a much stronger impact on incomes. Openness (trade/GDP) has a negative impact on income levels and democracy, but a positive effect on rule of law. Higher income produces greater openness and better institutions, but these effects are not very strong. Rule of law and democracy tend to be mutually reinforcing.  相似文献   

12.
13.
14.
This study provides further evidence of the inflationary efects of the rates of growth of money supply, gross domestic product, efective exchange rate, and imported inflation for Egypt, Morocco, and Tunisia using quarterly data from 1964 to 1990. In addition, it examines the Granger causality between inflation and money supply as well as between inflation and the real exchange rate in the countries under consideration. Most of the results are consistent with extant theory and empirical evidence.  相似文献   

15.
16.
We bridge the gap between the standard theory of growth and the mostly static theory of corruption. Some public investment can be diverted from its purpose by corrupt individuals. Voters determine the level of public investment subject to an incentive constraint equalizing the returns from productive and corrupt activities. We concentrate on two exogenous institutional parameters: the “technology of corruption” is the ease with which rent‐seekers can capture a proportion of public spending. The “concentration of political power” is the extent to which rent‐seekers have more political influence than other people. One theoretical prediction is that the effects of the two institutional parameters on income growth and equilibrium corruption are different according to the constraints that are binding at equilibrium. In particular, the effect of judicial quality on growth should be stronger when political power is concentrated. We estimate a system of equations where both corruption and income growth are determined simultaneously and show that income growth is more affected by our proxies for legal and political institutions in countries where political rights and judicial institutions, respectively, are limited.  相似文献   

17.
We investigate the extent to which quality of judicial institutions has an impact on individuals’ propensity for criminal and dishonest behavior and on their views regarding the acceptability of dishonesty and law-breaking. We use micro data on residents of 25 European countries and employ alternative measures of judicial quality as perceived by the residents of these countries. As an instrument for judicial quality we employ the procedures with which prosecutors and judges are appointed to their posts in each country. As alternative instruments, we employ an index of de jure institutional quality as well as its components, which provide similar results. The findings show that an increase in the perception of the quality of judicial institutions, such as an improvement in judicial independence or the impartiality of the courts, has a deterrent effect on dishonest and criminal acts. A higher perceived quality of the judicial system also makes individuals less likely to find acceptable a variety of dishonest and illicit behaviors, suggesting that institutions help shape the beliefs of the society. We obtain the same results when we analyze the sample of immigrants, whose cultural attributes should be (more) related to their countries of origin, rather than their countries of residence, and thus should be arguably uncorrelated with the factors that can impact the instrument. We show that people’s beliefs in the importance of the family, in the fairness of others, and the importance of being rich are not impacted by judicial quality, suggesting that judicial quality is not a blanket representation of underlying cultural norms and beliefs in the society.  相似文献   

18.
The debate about the Prebisch-Singer thesis has focused on primary commodities with some extensions to manufactures. We analyse trends in country terms-of-trade for goods and services rather than those for commodities according to the World Bank income classification. We find that the natural logarithm of the terms of trade for all groups except for the poorest has common unit roots, but none has individual unit roots. As low-income countries have no unit roots over-differencing is inefficient and biases significance levels in first differences against the fall in the terms of trade. For the low-income countries the terms of trade of goods and services are falling at a rate that is significantly negative without and with endogeneity treatment by system GMM. A comprehensive analysis of the effects of time dummies supports the result of falling terms of trade for low-income countries. When all coefficients are country-specific 50% of all low-income countries have falling terms of trade in a simultaneous equation estimation using the SUR method. Food and financial crisis have no effect on the number of countries with falling terms of trade, but (dis-)improve the terms of trade or the significance of the results for a very small number of countries.  相似文献   

19.
20.
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号