首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
相似文献
 共查询到20条相似文献,搜索用时 31 毫秒
1.
We consider an agent who invests in a stock and a money market and consumes in order to maximize the utility of consumption over an infinite planning horizon in the presence of a proportional transaction cost . The utility function is of the form U(c) = c1-p/(1-p) for p > 0, . We provide a heuristic and a rigorous derivation of the asymptotic expansion of the value function in powers of , and we also obtain asymptotic results on the boundary of the no-trade region.Received: July 2003, Mathematics Subject Classification (1991): 90A09, 60H30, 60G44JEL Classification: G13Work supported by the National Science Foundation under grants DMS-0103814 and DMS-0139911.  相似文献   

2.
We define (d,n)-coherent risk measures as set-valued maps from into satisfying some axioms. We show that this definition is a convenient extension of the real-valued risk measures introduced by Artzner et al. [2]. We then discuss the aggregation issue, i.e., the passage from valued random portfolio to valued measure of risk. Necessary and sufficient conditions of coherent aggregation are provided.Received: February 2004, Mathematics Subject Classification (2000): 91B30, 46E30JEL Classification: D81, G31  相似文献   

3.
4.
5.
6.
Robust utility maximization for complete and incomplete market models   总被引:2,自引:0,他引:2  
We investigate the problem of maximizing the robust utility functional . We give the dual characterization for its solution for both a complete and an incomplete market model. To this end, we introduce the new notion of reverse f-projections and use techniques developed for f-divergences. This is a suitable tool to reduce the robust problem to the classical problem of utility maximization under a certain measure: the reverse f-projection. Furthermore, we give the dual characterization for a closely related problem, the minimization of expenditures given a minimum level of expected utility in a robust setting and for an incomplete market.Received: September 2004, Mathematics Subject Classification (2000): 62C20, 62O05, 91B16, 91B28JEL Classification: D81, G11I thank Hans Föllmer for his help when writing this paper. Furthermore, I thank Alexander Schied for discussing the topic with me and Michael Kupper and the referees for their helpful remarks.  相似文献   

7.
In this paper the neutral valuation approach is applied to American and game options in incomplete markets. Neutral prices occur if investors are utility maximizers and if derivative supply and demand are balanced. Game contingent claims are derivative contracts that can be terminated by both counterparties at any time before expiration. They generalize American options where this right is limited to the buyer of the claim. It turns out that as in the complete case, the price process of American and game contingent claims corresponds to a Snell envelope or to the value of a Dynkin game, respectively.On the technical level, an important role is played by -sub- and -supermartingales. We characterize these processes in terms of semimartingale characteristics.Received: June 2003, Mathematics Subject Classification (2000):   91B24, 60G48, 91B16, 91A15, 60G40JEL Classification:   G13, D52, C73The authors want to thank PD Dr. Martin Beibel for the idea leading to the proof of Proposition A.4 and both anonymous referees for many valuable comments. The second author gratefully acknowledges financial support by the Deutsche Forschungsgemeinschaft through the Graduiertenkolleg Angewandte Algorithmische Mathematik at Munich University of Technology and by the Fonds zur Förderung der wissenschaftlichen Forschung at Vienna University of Technology.  相似文献   

8.
In this paper, we consider trading with proportional transaction costs as in Schachermayer’s paper (Schachermayer in Math. Finance 14:19–48, 2004). We give a necessary and sufficient condition for , the cone of claims attainable from zero endowment, to be closed. Then we show how to define a revised set of trading prices in such a way that, firstly, the corresponding cone of claims attainable for zero endowment, , does obey the fundamental theorem of asset pricing and, secondly, if is arbitrage-free then it is the closure of . We then conclude by showing how to represent claims.   相似文献   

9.
Lookback options have payoffs dependent on the maximum and/or minimum of the underlying price attained during the options lifetime. Based on the relationship between diffusion maximum and minimum and hitting times and the spectral decomposition of diffusion hitting times, this paper gives an analytical characterization of lookback option prices in terms of spectral expansions. In particular, analytical solutions for lookback options under the constant elasticity of variance (CEV) diffusion are obtained.Received: 1 October 2003, Mathematics Subject Classification: 60J35, 60J60, 60G70JEL Classification: G13The author thanks Phelim Boyle for bringing the problem of pricing lookback options under the CEV process to his attention and for useful discussions and Viatcheslav Gorovoi for computational assistance. This research was supported by the U.S. National Science Foundation under grants DMI-0200429 and DMS-0223354.  相似文献   

10.
The Journal of Finance has published an important paper entitled A Simple Econometric Approach for Utility-Based Asset Pricing Model by Brown and Gibbon (1985). The main purpose of this paper is to extend the research of Brown and Gibbons (1985) and Karson, Cheng and Lee (1995) in estimating the relative risk aversion (RRA) parameter in utility-based asset pricing model. First, we review the distributions of RRA parameter estimate . Then, a new method to the distribution of is derived, and a Bayesian approach for the inference of is proposed. Finally, empirical results are presented by using market rate of return and riskless rate data during the period December 1925 through December 2001.  相似文献   

11.
12.
The Lévy term structure model due to Eberlein and Raible is extended to non-homogeneous driving processes. The classes of equivalent martingale and local martingale measures for various filtrations are characterized. It turns out that in a number of standard situations the martingale measure is unique.Received: May 2004, Mathematics Subject Classification (2000): 60H30, 91B28, 60G51JEL Classification: E43, G13Work supported in part by the European Communitys Human Potential Programme under contract HPRN-CT-2000-00100, DYNSTOCH.  相似文献   

13.
This study tests the validity of the critical assumption underlying the option pricing model that the log form of the stock price movements follows the Wiener process, i.e., stock price movements follow a geometric Brownian motion. Using data compiled from the Taiwan Stock Exchange (TSE), this study's major empirical findings are as follows: first, the null hypothesis that the log of the stock prices is normally distributed is rejected; second, the null hypothesis that the stock price in log form has mean [ln P s + (µ- 2)t] and variance t is rejected; third, the null hypothesis that successive non-overlapping increments of the log of the stock price are independent from each other is also rejected. These empirical findings undermine the validity of the Wiener process assumption which is fundamental to many option pricing models.  相似文献   

14.
15.
We study the parametric problem of estimating the drift coefficient in a stochastic volatility model , where Y is a log price process and V the volatility process. Assuming that one can recover the volatility, precisely enough, from the observation of the price process, we construct an efficient estimator for the drift parameter of the diffusion V. As an application we present the efficient estimation based on the discrete sampling with δ n →0 and n δ n →∞. We show that our setup is general enough to cover the case of ‘microstructure noise’ for the price process as well.   相似文献   

16.
17.
We prove a sharp upper bound for the error $\mathbb {E}|g(X)-g(\hat{X})|^{p}We prove a sharp upper bound for the error in terms of moments of , where X and are random variables and the function g is a function of bounded variation. We apply the results to the approximation of a solution to a stochastic differential equation at time T by the Euler scheme, and show that the approximation of the payoff of the binary option has asymptotically sharp strong convergence rate 1/2. This has consequences for multilevel Monte Carlo methods. The author was supported by the Finnish Graduate School in Stochastics and Statistics, the Ellen and Artturi Nyyss?nen Foundation, and the Academy of Finland, project #110599.  相似文献   

18.
An example of indifference prices under exponential preferences   总被引:10,自引:0,他引:10  
The aim herein is to analyze utility-based prices and hedging strategies. The analysis is based on an explicitly solved example of a European claim written on a nontraded asset, in a model where risk preferences are exponential, and the traded and nontraded asset are diffusion processes with, respectively, lognormal and arbitrary dynamics. Our results show that a nonlinear pricing rule emerges with certainty equivalent characteristics, yielding the price as a nonlinear expectation of the derivatives payoff under the appropriate pricing measure. The latter is a martingale measure that minimizes its relative to the historical measure entropy.Received: July 2003, Mathematics Subject Classification: 93E20, 60G40, 60J75JEL Classification: C61, G11, G13The second author acknowledges partial support from NSF Grants DMS-0102909 and DMS-0091946. We have received valuable comments from the participants at the Conferences in Paris IX, Dauphine (2000), ICBI Barcelona (2001) and 14th Annual Conference of FORC Warwick (2001). While revising this work, we came across the paper by Henderson (2002) in which a special case of our model is investigated  相似文献   

19.
The skew effect in market implied volatility can be reproduced by option pricing theory based on stochastic volatility models for the price of the underlying asset. Here we study the performance of the calibration of the S&P 500 implied volatility surface using the asymptotic pricing theory under fast mean-reverting stochastic volatility described in [8]. The time-variation of the fitted skew-slope parameter shows a periodic behaviour that depends on the option maturity dates in the future, which are known in advance. By extending the mathematical analysis to incorporate model parameters which are time-varying, we show this behaviour can be explained in a manner consistent with a large model class for the underlying price dynamics with time-periodic volatility coefficients.Received: December 2003, Mathematics Subject Classification (2000): 91B70, 60F05, 60H30JEL Classification: C13, G13Jean-Pierre Fouque: Work partially supported by NSF grant DMS-0071744.Ronnie Sircar: Work supported by NSF grant DMS-0090067. We are grateful to Peter Thurston for research assistance.We thank a referee for his/her comments which improved the paper.  相似文献   

20.
We consider a multi-stock market model where prices satisfy a stochastic differential equation with instantaneous rates of return modeled as a continuous time Markov chain with finitely many states. Partial observation means that only the prices are observable. For the investors objective of maximizing the expected utility of the terminal wealth we derive an explicit representation of the optimal trading strategy in terms of the unnormalized filter of the drift process, using HMM filtering results and Malliavin calculus. The optimal strategy can be determined numerically and parameters can be estimated using the EM algorithm. The results are applied to historical prices.Received: March 2004, Mathematics Subject Classification (2000): 91B28, 60G44JEL Classification: G11Supported by NSERC under research grant 88051 and NCE grant 30354.  相似文献   

设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号