首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   135505篇
  免费   3822篇
  国内免费   3篇
财政金融   25855篇
工业经济   11142篇
计划管理   21835篇
经济学   29722篇
综合类   1470篇
运输经济   965篇
旅游经济   2514篇
贸易经济   22528篇
农业经济   6146篇
经济概况   16890篇
信息产业经济   8篇
邮电经济   255篇
  2021年   836篇
  2020年   1639篇
  2019年   2409篇
  2018年   2398篇
  2017年   2576篇
  2016年   2742篇
  2015年   2106篇
  2014年   3423篇
  2013年   15367篇
  2012年   4247篇
  2011年   4231篇
  2010年   3755篇
  2009年   4374篇
  2008年   3957篇
  2007年   3299篇
  2006年   3594篇
  2005年   3584篇
  2004年   3137篇
  2003年   2902篇
  2002年   2853篇
  2001年   2697篇
  2000年   2593篇
  1999年   2497篇
  1998年   2365篇
  1997年   2400篇
  1996年   2081篇
  1995年   2001篇
  1994年   1984篇
  1993年   1951篇
  1992年   1962篇
  1991年   1905篇
  1990年   1762篇
  1989年   1582篇
  1988年   1518篇
  1987年   1545篇
  1986年   1615篇
  1985年   2380篇
  1984年   2273篇
  1983年   2069篇
  1982年   1929篇
  1981年   1910篇
  1980年   1870篇
  1979年   1786篇
  1978年   1602篇
  1977年   1582篇
  1976年   1358篇
  1975年   1244篇
  1974年   1160篇
  1973年   1150篇
  1972年   863篇
排序方式: 共有10000条查询结果,搜索用时 390 毫秒
911.
Does Hedging Affect Firm Value? Evidence from the US Airline Industry   总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1  
Does hedging add value to the firm, and if so, is the source of the added value consistent with hedging theory? We investigate jet fuel hedging behavior of firms in the US airline industry during 1992–2003 to examine whether such hedging is a source of value for these companies. We illustrate that the investment and financing climate in the airline industry conforms well to the theoretical framework of Froot, Scharfstein, and Stein (1993). In general, airline industry investment opportunities correlate positively with jet fuel costs, while higher fuel costs are consistent with lower cash flow. Given that jet fuel costs are hedgeable, airlines with a desire for expansion may find value in hedging future purchases of jet fuel. Our results show that jet fuel hedging is positively related to airline firm value. The coefficients on the hedging variables in our regression analysis suggest that the “hedging premium” is greater than the 5% documented in Allayannis and Weston (2001), and might be as large as 10%. We find that the positive relation between hedging and value increases in capital investment, and that most of the hedging premium is attributable to the interaction of hedging with investment. This result is consistent with the assertion that the principal benefit of jet fuel hedging by airlines comes from reduction of underinvestment costs.  相似文献   
912.
Beef cattle producers were surveyed in Texas and Nebraska to investigate perceptions of sources of risk, the effectiveness of risk management strategies, and interest in further risk management education, particularly production risk, using probit analysis. Important decision variables identified are age, prior use of risk management tools, previous attendances of risk management education, and risk aversion. Severe drought and cattle price variability are identified as primary risk factors with potential to affect farm income. Extremely cold weather and disease are of less importance. Understocking pasture and storing hay are perceived most effective as risk management options.  相似文献   
913.
914.
What Kind of Voice Do Loyal Employees Use?   总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1  
This study helps clarify mixed support for Hirschman's exit–voice–loyalty framework by arguing that loyalty, or feelings of attachment to the organization, and voice are not one–dimensional constructs. Based on data gathered from a survey of employees working with a large Canadian utility organization, employees feeling attached through an affective, emotional bond are found less likely to use representative voice but more likely to use direct voice, while those attached for rational, calculated reasons are more likely to use representative voice. Employees feeling attached for either reason are found less likely to exit. Implications for theory, research, and policy are discussed.  相似文献   
915.
We examine the impact of initial public offerings (IPOs) on rival firms and find that the valuation effects are insignificant. This insignificant reaction can be explained by offsetting information and competitive effects. Significant positive information effects are associated with IPOs in regulated industries and the first IPO in an industry following a period of dormancy. Significant negative competitive effects are associated with larger IPOs in competitive industries, those in relatively risky industries, those in high‐performing industries, and those in the technology sector. IPO firms that use the proceeds for debt repayment appear to represent a more significant competitive threat to rival firms relative to IPO firms that use their proceeds for other purposes.  相似文献   
916.
This paper formalizes the commonsensical hypothesis that resource scarcity causes a large allocation of time and effort to appropriative competition. Our main innovation is to model explicitly the positive intertemporal effect of consumption on the probability of survival. The critical assumption is that this effect becomes stronger as resources become scarcer. We also show that anticipated future resource abundance increases the incremental value of survival and, consequently, amplifies the current allocation of time and effort to appropriative competition. Interestingly, if resources are currently scarce, then larger anticipated future abundance can cause a big enough increase in the time and effort allocated to appropriative competition to result in a decrease in the sum of current and expected future utility, a “paradox of anticipated abundance”.  相似文献   
917.
Monopoly, competition and information acquisition   总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1  
An incumbent monopolist is uncertain about its linear demand, but can acquire public information at a cost. We determine how an entry threat affects the firm's information acquisition. If returns to scale are constant and the state-contingent demands become more dispersed as output increases, then entry reduces information acquisition. If, however, either the incumbent or entrant has increasing returns; or if the state-contingent demands are nonlinear or fail increasing dispersion, then entry can increase information. Finally, entry can hurt consumers. Although entry always increases output, it can decrease information. Consumers sometimes prefer a better informed monopoly to a duopoly.  相似文献   
918.
Popular monthly coincident indices of business cycles, e.g. the composite index and the Stock–Watson coincident index, have two shortcomings. First, they ignore information contained in quarterly indicators such as real GDP. Second, they lack economic interpretation; hence the heights of peaks and the depths of troughs depend on the choice of an index. This paper extends the Stock–Watson coincident index by applying maximum likelihood factor analysis to a mixed‐frequency series of quarterly real GDP and monthly coincident business cycle indicators. The resulting index is related to latent monthly real GDP. Copyright © 2002 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.  相似文献   
919.
Kirzner, Israel M. (2001). Ludwig von Mises: The Man and His Economics . Wilmington, DE: ISI Books. ISBN 1-882926-61-7. xv, 226 pp.  相似文献   
920.
A BSTRACT . Searle's philosophical construction of social reality has three basic "building blocks": collective intentionality, constitutive rules, and the imposition of functions. This article will focus on the first of these, collective intentionality, which is taken to be the central span on the bridge from physics to society. Searle analyzes this notion in terms of his own internalist theory of intentionality. In his view, we could have all the collective intentionality we have even if we were a brain in a vat, i.e., even if we were radically mistaken about the outside world. It will be argued that such an internalist view of collective intentionality cannot capture normative aspects of social phenomena. Social reality requires a radical relational approach.  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号