首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   346篇
  免费   15篇
财政金融   56篇
工业经济   30篇
计划管理   67篇
经济学   87篇
综合类   4篇
运输经济   6篇
旅游经济   2篇
贸易经济   73篇
农业经济   13篇
经济概况   22篇
邮电经济   1篇
  2023年   4篇
  2022年   2篇
  2021年   6篇
  2020年   9篇
  2019年   8篇
  2018年   9篇
  2017年   13篇
  2016年   9篇
  2015年   6篇
  2014年   14篇
  2013年   38篇
  2012年   14篇
  2011年   14篇
  2010年   16篇
  2009年   14篇
  2008年   15篇
  2007年   9篇
  2006年   12篇
  2005年   10篇
  2004年   7篇
  2003年   6篇
  2002年   10篇
  2001年   6篇
  2000年   8篇
  1999年   8篇
  1998年   6篇
  1997年   6篇
  1996年   8篇
  1995年   8篇
  1993年   4篇
  1992年   7篇
  1991年   5篇
  1989年   2篇
  1988年   2篇
  1986年   4篇
  1985年   3篇
  1984年   4篇
  1983年   3篇
  1982年   3篇
  1981年   4篇
  1979年   2篇
  1977年   3篇
  1976年   2篇
  1975年   6篇
  1974年   2篇
  1968年   1篇
  1964年   1篇
  1960年   1篇
  1951年   1篇
  1862年   1篇
排序方式: 共有361条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
321.
322.
This paper estimates nitrogen fertilizer demand elasticities for Danish crop farms using the dual profit function approach on micro panel data. The model includes several farm‐specific parameters, allowing us to estimate the mean demand elasticity and test for homogeneity of elasticities across panel farms. The mean own‐price elasticity for nitrogen is ?0.45, and there is a significant standard deviation from this mean for individual farms of 0.24. Heterogeneity of demand elasticities implies that regulating fertilizer application through mandated uniform percentage reductions, as is currently used in Danish nitrogen regulation, increases abatement costs relative to tax regulation. Somewhat surprisingly, this causes the abatement costs of quota regulation to be only 8% larger than with tax regulation. Simulation results indicate that the primary threat to the efficiency of uniform reduction schemes comes from inaccurate estimation of baselines rather than from heterogeneity of elasticities. L'auteur estime les élasticités de la demande d'engrais azotés pour l'agriculture danoise en appliquant la fonction du double profit aux données issues de microgroupes de consultation. Le modèle inclut plusieurs paramètres spécifiques à l'agriculture, ce qui permet d'estimer l'élasticité moyenne de la demande et de vérifier l'homogénéité des élasticités pour les agriculteurs consultés. On constate qu'il existe une élasticité‐prix moyenne de ?0,45 pour l'azote et que cette moyenne présente un écart‐type significatif de 0,24 par exploitation agricole. Les élasticités hétérogènes de la demande supposent que si on régule les engrais azotés par une réduction uniforme du volume employé en pour cent, ainsi que l'exige présentment le règlement danois, on accroît le coût des mesures de lutte, comparativement à ce qui se produit avec les mesures fiscales. Il est un peu surprenant de voir que la régulation par quota n'augmente le coût des mesures de lutte que de 8%, par rapport aux mesures fiscales. Les résultats de la simulation révèlent que l'efficacité des programmes de réduction uniforme est surtout menacée par une estimation inexacte des valeurs de base et non par l'hétérogénéité des élasticités.  相似文献   
323.
We analyse the Granger causal relationships between foreign direct investment (FDI) and GDP in a sample of 31 developing countries covering 31 years. Using estimators for heterogeneous panel data we find bi‐directional causality between the FDI‐to‐GDP ratio and the level of GDP. FDI has a lasting impact on GDP, while GDP has no long‐run impact on the FDI‐to‐GDP ratio. In that sense FDI causes growth. Furthermore, in a model for GDP and FDI as a fraction of gross capital formation (GCF) we also find long‐run effects from FDI to GDP. This finding may be interpreted as evidence in favour of the hypotheses that FDI has an impact on GDP via knowledge transfers and adoption of new technology.  相似文献   
324.
325.
Introducing T-shaped managers. Knowledge management's next generation   总被引:11,自引:0,他引:11  
Most companies do a poor job of capitalizing on the wealth of expertise scattered across their organizations. That's because they tend to rely on centralized knowledge-management systems and technologies. But such systems are really only good at distributing explicit knowledge, the kind that can be captured and codified for general use. They're not very good at transferring implicit knowledge, the kind needed to generate new insights and creative ways of tackling business problems or opportunities. The authors suggest another approach, something they call T-shaped management, which requires executives to share knowledge freely across their organization (the horizontal part of the "T"), while remaining fiercely committed to their individual business unit's performance (the vertical part). A few companies are starting to use this approach, and one--BP Amoco--has been especially successful. From BP's experience, the authors have gleaned five ways that T-shaped managers help companies capitalize on their inherent knowledge. They increase efficiency by transferring best practices. They improve the quality of decision making companywide. They grow revenues through shared expertise. They develop new business opportunities through the cross-pollination of ideas. And they make bold strategic moves possible by delivering well-coordinated implementation. All that takes time, and BP's managers have had to learn how to balance that time against the attention they must pay to their own units. The authors suggest, however, that it's worth the effort to find such a balance to more fully realize the immense value of the knowledge lying idle within so many companies.  相似文献   
326.
A prediction formula for geometrically declining sums of future forcing variables is derived for models in which the forcing variables are generated by a vector autoregressive-moving average process. This formula is useful in deducing and characterizing cross-equation restrictions implied by linear rational expectations models.  相似文献   
327.
328.
This article uses factor models to identify and estimate the distributions of counterfactuals. We extend LISREL frameworks to a dynamic treatment effect setting, extending matching to account for unobserved conditioning variables. Using these models, we can identify all pairwise and joint treatment effects. We apply these methods to a model of schooling and determine the intrinsic uncertainty facing agents at the time they make their decisions about enrollment in school. We go beyond the “Veil of Ignorance” in evaluating educational policies and determine who benefits and who loses from commonly proposed educational reforms.  相似文献   
329.
The demise of the rights issue   总被引:2,自引:0,他引:2  
This article suggests that the lack of use of rights offeringsin the United States, a phenomenon referred to as the equityunderwriting paradox, can be explained by transaction-cost conditions.A sample of underwritten rights offerings provides support forthe explanation. Firms making underwritten rights offeringspaid lower underwriter fees but incurred significantly largerprice drops just prior to the offering than did firms makingunderwritten public offerings. Further analysis reveals thatthe underwritten-rights-offering price concessions are a formof transaction cost that is not found in under-written publicofferings.  相似文献   
330.
The adjustment of product prices in open economies is analyzed by use of a model encompassing different product market structures and quarterly data for Denmark, Germany, the Netherlands, Norway, and Sweden. In general, support is found in favor of a specialized production model implying that prices are affected by internal and external factors. Price adjustment displays substantial inertia and is in the short run driven by real shocks to both supply and demand, as well as being characterized by nominal rigidities, whereas in the long run relative prices are driven solely by supply variables.  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号