首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   388篇
  免费   6篇
财政金融   25篇
工业经济   11篇
计划管理   76篇
经济学   99篇
贸易经济   118篇
农业经济   12篇
经济概况   53篇
  2021年   3篇
  2019年   2篇
  2018年   6篇
  2017年   6篇
  2016年   12篇
  2015年   5篇
  2014年   11篇
  2013年   27篇
  2012年   17篇
  2011年   12篇
  2010年   14篇
  2009年   10篇
  2008年   29篇
  2007年   8篇
  2006年   8篇
  2005年   7篇
  2004年   4篇
  2003年   8篇
  2002年   8篇
  2001年   12篇
  2000年   8篇
  1999年   7篇
  1998年   9篇
  1997年   10篇
  1996年   8篇
  1995年   12篇
  1994年   4篇
  1993年   7篇
  1992年   6篇
  1991年   8篇
  1990年   6篇
  1989年   4篇
  1988年   2篇
  1987年   6篇
  1986年   5篇
  1985年   6篇
  1984年   5篇
  1983年   6篇
  1982年   5篇
  1981年   5篇
  1980年   6篇
  1979年   5篇
  1978年   9篇
  1977年   4篇
  1976年   8篇
  1975年   6篇
  1974年   6篇
  1973年   2篇
  1972年   2篇
  1967年   3篇
排序方式: 共有394条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
41.
Conclusion When a technology proprietor cannot exploit his advantage by means of ownership of a production facility abroad, a sales contract with “buy-back provisions” may, in fact, be a trade-enhancing resolution to a situation of information-asymmetry between buyer and seller. The important implication is that not all forms of countertrade can be summarily dismissed as inefficient. Just as foreign direct investment can be seen to be a response to environmental or market imperfections, “buy-back” may be a way to deal with institutional or regulatory obstacles such as the prohibition of foreign ownership.  相似文献   
42.
43.
The article investigates how sensitive different dynamic and static hedge strategies for barrier options are to model risk. It is found that using plain‐vanilla options to hedge offers considerable improvements over usual Δ hedges. Further, it is shown that the hedge portfolios involving options are relatively more sensitive to model risk, but that the degree of misspecification sensitivity is robust across commonly used models. © 2006 Wiley Periodicals, Inc. Jrl Fut Mark 26:449–463, 2006  相似文献   
44.
Färe  Rolf 《Journal of Economics》1975,35(3-4):317-324
Journal of Economics -  相似文献   
45.
46.
47.
Conclusions The analyses have shown that ESACs unprecedented emergence in world trade and capital transactions has been accompanied by a growing share of intra-area transactions. At least for the goods sector, the evidence is clear. Intra-area transactions grew faster than those to the rest of world, and the latter rose faster than world trade. Given this “double growth” performance, there was no trade diversion in the static zero sum meaning. Driving forces of fast growing intra-area transactions were basically internal conditions, such as “natural” trading partnership (geographical and cultural proximity, size, and complementarity in resource endowment and production structure), rising income levels fostering intra-industry trade, the economic opening of China, and unilateral liberalisation of trade and capital transactions on a non-discriminatory basis. It cannot be denied that external factors as protectionism and recession in non-Asian OECD countries have also contributed to this performance. Yet, it seems safe to assume that even without the US and European recession in the early eighties and early nineties and without the spread on non-tariff barriers, intraarea transactions would have received sufficient fuels from the internal factors to grow more rapidly than transactions with the rest of the world.17 Furthermore, a base effect of a low initial level of intra-area trade cannot be neglected.  相似文献   
48.
The reform programmes of most Eastern European countries have liberalized prices and taken on the task of macroeconomic stabilization, but the formation and implementation of structural policies has largely been neglected so far. What steps should the governments of Eastern Europe take to encourage the necessary restructuring of their economies and to attract the urgently needed foreign investment?  相似文献   
49.
50.
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号