首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   93篇
  免费   5篇
财政金融   15篇
工业经济   2篇
计划管理   24篇
经济学   32篇
贸易经济   17篇
农业经济   1篇
经济概况   4篇
邮电经济   3篇
  2023年   1篇
  2022年   1篇
  2021年   1篇
  2020年   2篇
  2019年   2篇
  2018年   2篇
  2017年   2篇
  2016年   3篇
  2015年   2篇
  2014年   1篇
  2013年   11篇
  2012年   9篇
  2011年   4篇
  2010年   3篇
  2009年   5篇
  2008年   1篇
  2007年   4篇
  2006年   3篇
  2005年   7篇
  2004年   1篇
  2003年   5篇
  2002年   2篇
  2001年   6篇
  2000年   2篇
  1999年   6篇
  1997年   2篇
  1996年   1篇
  1995年   1篇
  1994年   1篇
  1992年   1篇
  1991年   1篇
  1989年   2篇
  1988年   1篇
  1987年   1篇
  1981年   1篇
排序方式: 共有98条查询结果,搜索用时 328 毫秒
61.
This paper presents the design of an extended matchmaking component for electronic markets, which is able to identify negotiable agreements and the issues that are subject to the negotiation, in the case where basic matchmaking fails to find agreements that satisfy the constraints of the seller and the buyer. The foundation for this functionality is the introduction of negotiable constraints within the offer specification process. The extended matchmaking component complements our SilkRoad design and implementation framework for electronic negotiations. This framework also features other negotiation service components such as a mediation service, which may use the feedback from the extended matchmaking operation on agreement candidates and negotiation spaces, to suggest fair agreements on the basis of the Adjusted Winner algorithm for dispute resolution.  相似文献   
62.
The public sectors in the Scandinavian countries have been prominent examples of centralized wage-setting systems. In Norway, more room for local flexibility was implemented by a wage frame system introduced in 1990 in which the national wage scale system merely works like a minimum wage system. We analyze the effect of this reform using a unique database where we can track employees and their local government over time and explore the consequences of controlling for fixed individual effects and fixed employer effects. We find that the wage dispersion increased across local governments after 1990, and that wages to some extent became more responsive to local government income, monopsony power and other local government characteristics after the reform. However, the numerical effects of the reform are estimated to be quite small.  相似文献   
63.
We establish necessary and sufficient conditions for a linear taxation system to be neutral—within the multi-period discrete time “no arbitrage” model—in the sense that valuation is invariant to the exact sequence of tax rates, realization dates as well as immune to timing options attempting to twist the time profile of taxable income through wash sale transactions.
“In the study of investments, taxes are largely a source of embarrassment to financial economists.” (Introduction to Dybvig and Ross 1986) “Accordingly, my approach in this chapter is to examine the restrictions on the income measurement rules applicable to financial instruments implied by the requirement that the rules be linear. . . . Linearity is a desideratum of a tidy tax system.” (Bradford 2000, p. 373–374)
  相似文献   
64.
We reexamine the negative relation between firm value and the number of antitakeover provisions a firm has in place. We document that firms with characteristics indicating low power to bargain for favorable terms in a takeover, but also indicating high potential agency costs, have more antitakeover provisions in place. We also find that for these firms, Tobin's Q increases in the number of adopted provisions. These findings are robust to several methods that control for endogeneity. Our evidence suggests that adopting more antitakeover provisions is beneficial for certain firms and challenges the commonplace view that antitakeover provisions are universally harmful for shareholders.  相似文献   
65.
Institutional, or sector-by-sector input–output tables have traditionally been used in regional and interregional modelling. This paper examines the origins of this tradition and argues instead, both theoretically and empirically, for the integration of make and use submodels within models of production, demand and interregional trade, outlining the manner in which they can be integrated. Further, it is argued that structural rather than reduced-form models represent a sounder theoretical base. Finally, a Danish interregional model (LINE) based on a social accounting matrix framework that employs these principles is presented. The paper also deals with the issue of data construction at the regional and interregional levels, based on the make and use approach. It is argued that when data are constructed at a low level of sectoral and spatial aggregation under accounting consistency constraints, data quality and validity are high.  相似文献   
66.
Campa  Pamela  Roine  Jesper  Strömberg  Svante 《Intereconomics》2021,56(5):264-269
Intereconomics - So, when asked if men and women in the Swedish labour market have been differently affected by the COVID-19 pandemic, our overall conclusion would have to be “no”.  相似文献   
67.
In this action research study, we show by several cases that a synthetic innovation style in combination with an entrepreneurial culture might increase innovations for safety. Rational decisions and early product specifications were replaced by a natural selection of ideas in an acting reality to have the most fitted ideas among the actors. The forthcoming ideas actually ruled the development of the process and the business set-up like in an entrepreneurial culture. With financial support from the Swedish research funds, Vinnova and SBUF, a laboratory for both research and innovation was implemented at the Karolinska Institutet. The laboratory emanated from an initiative of Professor Leif Svanstr?m in developing a multidisciplinary collaboration on design and consumer safety. In this review, we present our promising findings.  相似文献   
68.
69.
This article shows how a CRESH (Constant Ratios of Elasticity of Substitution, Homothetic) labour index can generate more realistic optimal wage profiles than traditional (restrictive) functional forms. The CRESH index function allows for age-specific elasticities of substitution that are implied by a proper choice of CRESH parameters. The ability to generate plausible optimal age-wage profiles can be useful in, for example, calibrating demographic macroeconomic models. The CRESH analysis also provides one explanation for the well-established divergence of actual relative wages by age from the relative age-specific intensity parameters of a simple additive labour index. Moreover, CRESH labour index may explain the increasing relative wages for middle-aged workers as a result of employing larger numbers of older workers (population aging).  相似文献   
70.
The objective of this paper is to analyze criteria for portfolio choice when two investors are forced to invest in a common portfolio and share the proceeds by a linear sharing rule. A similar situation with many investors is typical for defined contribution pension schemes. The restriction implies two sources of suboptimal investment decisions as seen from each of the two investors individually. One is the suboptimal choice of portfolio, the other is the forced linear sharing rule. We measure the combined consequence for each investor by their respective loss in wealth equivalent. We show that significant losses can arise when investors are diverse in their risk attitude. We also show that an investor with a low degree of risk aversion, like the logarithmic or the square root investor, often applied in portfolio choice models, can either inflict or be subject to severe losses when being forced to participate in such a common investment pool.  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号