首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   399篇
  免费   21篇
财政金融   73篇
工业经济   27篇
计划管理   65篇
经济学   78篇
综合类   8篇
运输经济   1篇
旅游经济   7篇
贸易经济   97篇
农业经济   30篇
经济概况   34篇
  2023年   4篇
  2022年   4篇
  2021年   4篇
  2020年   4篇
  2019年   8篇
  2018年   12篇
  2017年   14篇
  2016年   9篇
  2015年   13篇
  2014年   12篇
  2013年   45篇
  2012年   16篇
  2011年   8篇
  2010年   20篇
  2009年   22篇
  2008年   18篇
  2007年   13篇
  2006年   18篇
  2005年   11篇
  2004年   13篇
  2003年   10篇
  2002年   7篇
  2001年   8篇
  2000年   5篇
  1999年   11篇
  1998年   13篇
  1997年   13篇
  1996年   6篇
  1995年   5篇
  1994年   4篇
  1993年   6篇
  1992年   8篇
  1991年   3篇
  1990年   5篇
  1989年   2篇
  1988年   5篇
  1985年   3篇
  1984年   2篇
  1983年   4篇
  1982年   3篇
  1981年   2篇
  1980年   3篇
  1979年   3篇
  1978年   4篇
  1977年   6篇
  1976年   2篇
  1975年   2篇
  1974年   2篇
  1969年   1篇
  1960年   1篇
排序方式: 共有420条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
91.
Technological advances are creating a shift in the information disclosure environment allowing more investors to interact with management. We examine three key levels of trader-management interaction to assess the accuracy of traders' market-tested value estimates and resulting market price. These data require an engaging experiment and a complex, contextually rich asset, which we create by playing a popular gaming app before the experiment. Participants view financial information, ask management questions, estimate value, and trade. We find that receiving non-personalized question responses improves trader estimates of value and market price efficiency relative to when traders ask questions but do not expect a response. This occurs because traders exert more effort estimating value and trading. However, receiving personalized versus non-personalized responses harms value estimates and market efficiency. This occurs because traders receiving personalized responses fixate on the interaction with management, dividing their attention and diverting it away from valuing and trading the asset.  相似文献   
92.
This note extends the Initial partial-mean concept for present worth analysis of risk by Buck and Askin (1986) to a two random variable case where the magnitude of a single cash flow Is a random variable, and the time duration is a random variable with uniform distribution. This extension leads to the calculation of the expected magnitude of a project loss given that the loss occurs. Computational formulas and numerical Illustrations are presented.  相似文献   
93.
We develop a model of games with awareness that allows for differential levels of awareness. We show that, for the standard modal-logical interpretations of belief and awareness, a player cannot believe there exist propositions of which he is unaware. Nevertheless, we argue that a boundedly rational individual may regard the possibility that there exist propositions of which she is unaware as being supported by inductive reasoning, based on past experience and consideration of the limited awareness of others. In this paper, we provide a formal representation of inductive reasoning in the context of a dynamic game with differential awareness. We show that, given differential awareness over time and between players, individuals can derive inductive support for propositions expressing their own unawareness. We consider the ecological rationality of heuristics to guide decisions in problems involving differential awareness.  相似文献   
94.
Pension reforms in many developed countries make individuals shoulder a bigger share of longevity and income risks. The desired response is that individuals accumulate private assets for retirement. Whether this actually takes place, is of paramount relevance for scientists and policy makers. We take Germany as an example: Twenty years of pension reform have transformed the monolithic German pension system into a multipillar system. Formerly generous public pension benefits are gradually being reduced, whereas substantial incentives are granted to occupational and private saving schemes. Has this transition worked out? We survey the reform steps and households’ reactions: How did individuals adjust their labor market behavior? How did private and occupational pension plans take off? How do behavioral adjustments vary in the population? Most Germans adapted to the new situation. Both actual and expected retirement decisions changed and the share of households without supplementary pensions decreased from 73% to 39% in little more than a decade. This is a remarkable success. Nonetheless, households with low education, low income and less financial education did neither adjust their retirement behavior nor pick up supplementary pension plans and are thus likely to face difficulties in bridging the gap arising in future pension income.  相似文献   
95.
Despite or because of the relatively brief concluding document of the Belgrade follow-up meeting mandated to examine the implementation of the Helsinki Final Act, it is worthwhile to review the proposals made in “Basket II“ (economics) and relate them to the two other “Baskets“ (security and “human rights“) in order to understand the process of détente more thoroughly.  相似文献   
96.
We investigate the role of the liquidity of stocks traded by mutual funds on the performance of funds experiencing substantial and sustained redemptions (outflows) or inflows. Accordingly, we identify 770 redeeming fund‐periods and 1,757 inflow fund‐periods and find a statistically significant relation between the liquidity of the stocks they trade and the quantity of the stock traded. Notably, when funds experience redemptions, those with low portfolio liquidity have an elevated preference for selling more‐liquid stocks. In the following period, such funds statistically and economically underperform funds that sell less‐liquid stocks. This is consistent with redemptions detrimentally affecting shareholders that remain in a fund.  相似文献   
97.
98.
The role of a subcultural group in the consumer acculturation of Kenyan immigrants is examined. Our findings demonstrate that particular immigrant consumer behaviors are influenced by triple acculturation forces: dominant; subcultural and original culture. We find that immigrants do not arrive in the United States aware of their need to acculturate to a subcultural group. Critical incidents alert the immigrants of the need to acculturate to the African American subculture in order to fulfill some basic consumer goals such as accessing hair care, nightclub entertainment and church services. Progressively, immigrants begin to incorporate triple acculturation forces in their consumer decision making. The immigrants learn to be innovative as well as to engage in satisficing as they navigate the new consumption environment. This research contributes to acculturation studies by extending the models of Berry (Berry JW. Acculturation as varieties of adaptation. In: Padilla AM, editor. Acculturation: theory, model and some new findings, Boulder, CO: Westview Press; 1980. pp. 9-25) as well as Penaloza (Penaloza L. Altravesando Fronteras/Border Crossings: a critical ethnographic exploration of the consumer acculturation of Mexican immigrants. J Consum Res 1994;2:32-54[June]) by incorporating the role of a subcultural group in this process.  相似文献   
99.
100.
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号