首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   182篇
  免费   8篇
财政金融   30篇
工业经济   20篇
计划管理   22篇
经济学   58篇
运输经济   1篇
旅游经济   4篇
贸易经济   32篇
农业经济   7篇
经济概况   16篇
  2023年   1篇
  2021年   1篇
  2019年   7篇
  2018年   5篇
  2017年   6篇
  2016年   3篇
  2015年   3篇
  2014年   1篇
  2013年   17篇
  2012年   4篇
  2011年   5篇
  2010年   6篇
  2009年   3篇
  2008年   3篇
  2007年   2篇
  2006年   3篇
  2005年   7篇
  2004年   4篇
  2003年   4篇
  2002年   2篇
  2001年   3篇
  2000年   5篇
  1999年   4篇
  1998年   3篇
  1997年   2篇
  1996年   8篇
  1994年   3篇
  1993年   8篇
  1992年   13篇
  1991年   10篇
  1990年   7篇
  1989年   3篇
  1988年   3篇
  1987年   5篇
  1986年   3篇
  1985年   2篇
  1984年   5篇
  1983年   1篇
  1981年   2篇
  1980年   2篇
  1979年   2篇
  1978年   3篇
  1976年   1篇
  1975年   1篇
  1974年   1篇
  1972年   2篇
  1971年   1篇
排序方式: 共有190条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
71.
An expansive literature exists linking institutional constraints, credible commitments, and economic growth. Yet, this literature runs into difficulty when it tries to explain the East Asian “paradox:” rapid economic growth achieved by countries with low levels of formal constraints on government discretion. We use a behavioral theory of commitment to argue that the characteristics of the salient actors (governments) and their actions (policies) affect the credibility of their behaviors in ways independent of the structural underpinnings of a country’s political institutions. This behavioral theory of commitment provides a distinct but complementary lens through which to view the apparent paradox presented by these East Asian countries, and more generally provides an alternative theoretical mechanism to explain and predict governments’ ability to credibly signal their commitment to a course of action to investing firms. The success of East Asian countries in encouraging investment from both domestic and foreign firms implies that firms interpret governments’ actions as credible signals of their intention to honor their commitments to firms, consistent with the behavioral theory of commitment.  相似文献   
72.
73.
74.
Prior archival studies of analysts' forecasts have found evidence for systematic underreaction, systematic overreaction, and systematic optimism bias. Easterwood and Nutt (1999) attempt to reconcile the conflicting evidence by testing the robustness of Abarbanell and Bernard's (1992) underreaction results to the nature of the information. Consistent with systematic optimism, forecasts are found to underreact to negative earnings information but overreact to positive information. However, Easterwood and Nutt are unable to distinguish between misreaction caused by incentives unique to analysts with misreaction caused by human decision bias that may be typical of investors. We address this issue by analyzing forecast reactions to positive versus negative information in the controlled experimental setting of Gillette, Stevens, Watts, and Williams (1999). The forecast data reveal systematic underreaction to both positive and negative information, and the underreaction is generally greater for positive information than negative information. This suggests that prior empirical evidence of forecast overreaction to positive information is unlikely to be attributable to human decision bias.  相似文献   
75.
76.
77.
Previous empirical analyses of job mobility focus on worker rather than firm characteristics. This paper exploits a unique data set on enterprise employment. We describe sectoral differences in turnover rates and in the persistence of turnover. We also present evidence of persistent turnover differences at the level of the individual firms—a result that is expected if firms have managers with differing ability to screen workers. When we consider the consequences to the firm of such turnover, we discover that high turnover firms are less likely to survive.  相似文献   
78.
The FASB's cost/benefit constraint in theory and practice   总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1  
The FASB in its Conceptual Framework has set high principles in the ethics of standard-setting in accounting. This paper concentrates on what the FASB calls the cost/benefit constraint, i.e., the commitment to setting an accounting standard only when the benefits of the standard exceeds the costs of that standard toall stakeholders. This constraint is supposed to take precedence over other concerns, such as neutrality (freedom from bias) of account information.The major conclusion of this paper is that a conflict exists between the FASB's commitment and its practice. There is no evidence that the FASB has always made a costs and benefits judgement with respect to proposed standards. In the cases when such a judgement is made, the FASB discounts social costs; therefore, it is not considering costs to all stakeholders. At the same time the FASB discounts social costs, it seems to have an undue concern for standards that do not increase the volatility of net income. The Conceptual Framework explicitly defines costs as the costs to society as a whole.Stanley Martens is an Assistant Professor of Accounting at DePaul University. He has written many articles for philosophy publications and accounting publications.Kevin Stevens is an Assistant Professor of Accounting at DePaul University. He has written many articles for various accounting publications.  相似文献   
79.
Accountants confronted with ethical dilemmas are expected to comply with their ethical guide or seek advice from their professional body. This study of Chartered Accountants in Ireland records their views on the usefulness of a Code of Ethics, the efficacy of their professional Institute and the need for ethics courses in Continuing Professional Development. Peter Clarke is a lecturer in the Department of Accountancy, University College Dublin, Dublin 4; Nancy Hill and Kevin Stevens are members of the School of Accountancy, DePaul University, Chicago.  相似文献   
80.
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号