首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   82篇
  免费   1篇
财政金融   30篇
工业经济   4篇
计划管理   6篇
经济学   15篇
贸易经济   1篇
农业经济   2篇
经济概况   25篇
  2024年   1篇
  2019年   1篇
  2015年   1篇
  2014年   1篇
  2013年   2篇
  2012年   1篇
  2011年   2篇
  2010年   4篇
  2009年   3篇
  2008年   4篇
  2007年   4篇
  2006年   2篇
  2005年   1篇
  2004年   2篇
  2002年   1篇
  2000年   4篇
  1999年   2篇
  1998年   1篇
  1997年   2篇
  1996年   1篇
  1995年   3篇
  1993年   3篇
  1992年   1篇
  1991年   1篇
  1990年   5篇
  1989年   2篇
  1988年   2篇
  1987年   4篇
  1986年   3篇
  1984年   1篇
  1983年   1篇
  1982年   1篇
  1981年   1篇
  1980年   1篇
  1979年   2篇
  1971年   2篇
  1970年   1篇
  1969年   2篇
  1967年   2篇
  1966年   1篇
  1965年   1篇
  1962年   1篇
  1959年   1篇
  1954年   1篇
排序方式: 共有83条查询结果,搜索用时 31 毫秒
1.
2.
Lead and lag relationships between money, wages. and prices are examined using Australian data. Granger causality tests support univariate causality running from money to both wages and prices. This result is consistent with a monetarist explanation of inflation.  相似文献   
3.
This paper generalizes Rubinstein and Wolinsky's (1987) model of middlemen (intermediation) by incorporating production and search costs, plus more general matching and bargaining. This allows us to study many new issues, including entry, efficiency, and dynamics. In the benchmark model, equilibrium exists uniquely and involves production and intermediation for some parameters but not others. Sometimes intermediation is essential: the market operates if and only if middlemen are active. If bargaining powers are set correctly equilibrium is efficient; if not there can be too much or too little economic activity. This is novel, compared to the original Rubinstein–Wolinsky model, where equilibrium is always efficient.  相似文献   
4.
5.
6.
7.
8.
9.
10.
This study examines the impact of alternative risk assessment (standard risk checklist versus no checklist) and program development (standard program versus no program) tools on two facets of fraud planning effectiveness: (1) the quality of audit procedures relative to a benchmark validated by a panel of experts, and (2) the propensity to consult fraud experts. A between‐subjects experiment, using an SEC enforcement fraud case, was conducted to examine these relationships. Sixty‐nine auditors made risk assessments and designed an audit program. We found that auditors who used a standard risk checklist, structured by SAS No. 82 risk categories, made lower risk assessments than those without a checklist. This suggests that the use of the checklist was associated with a less effective diagnosis of the fraud. We also found that auditors with a standard audit program designed a relatively less effective fraud program than those without this tool but were not more willing to seek consultation with fraud experts. This suggests that standard programs may impair auditors' ability to respond to fraud risk. Finally, our results show that fraud risk assessment (FRASK) was not associated with the planning of more effective fraud procedures but was directly associated with the desire to consult with fraud specialists. This suggests that one benefit of improved FRASK is its relation with consultation. Overall, the findings call into question the effectiveness of standard audit tools in a fraud setting and highlight the need for a more strategic reasoning approach in an elevated risk situation.  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号