共查询到20条相似文献,搜索用时 15 毫秒
1.
Raouf Boucekkine Marc Germain Omar Licandro Alphonse Magnus 《Journal of Economic Growth》1998,3(4):361-384
In this article, a new numerical procedure is used to compute the equilibrium of a vintage capital growth model with nonlinear utility, where the scrapping time is nonconstant. We show that equilibrium investment and output converge nonmonotonically to the balanced growth path due to replacement echoes. We find that the average age of capital is inversely related to output, which is consistent with recent micro evidence reinforcing the importance of the embodied question. We also find that an unanticipated permanent increase in the rate of embodied technological progress causes labor productivity to slowdown in the short run. 相似文献
2.
There has been much discussion of the sources of China’s growth slowdown but little formal econometric analysis of this question. Chen and Groenewold (2019) show that the slowdown was primarily supply-driven, but they stopped short of identifying specific supply variables. This paper extends their analysis and distinguishes several potential supply components: labor supply, productivity, and capital accumulation. Our results confirm their main conclusion that supply dominates the explanation of the slowdown. A model with two supply factors (labor supply and productivity) reveals that both components contribute to the slowdown, although productivity makes the greater contribution. However, when capital stock is added to the model, the decline in the capital accumulation rate becomes an important factor in the growth slowdown, to some extent replacing the effects of both labor supply and productivity. 相似文献
3.
Simón Ramírez Juan Gallego Mery Tamayo 《Economics of Innovation and New Technology》2020,29(6):625-642
ABSTRACT In this paper we explore the R&D–innovation–productivity linkage for the Colombian manufacturing industry, paying special attention to the role of human capital. Using data from two firm-level surveys, the Survey of Development and Technological Innovation (EDIT) and the Annual Manufacturing Survey (EAM), we extend the model of Crépon, Duguet, and Mairesse [1998. ‘Research, Innovation and Productivity: An Econometric Analysis at the Firm Level.’ Economics of Innovation and New Technology 7 (2): 115–158] (hereafter CDM) by including human capital at the investment decision stage. We implement an instrumental variable methodology to correct the potential endogeneity that may arise with the inclusion of human capital. Our results suggest that human capital has a causal effect on research and development (R&D) investment decisions, the innovation behavior of the firm, and increases the labor productivity of the firm. The conclusions highlight the relevance of human capital in the surrounding literature which stands in contrast to prior work that has not included this variable. 相似文献
4.
The standard assumption in growth accounting is that an hour worked by a worker of given type delivers a constant quantity of labor services over time. This assumption may be violated due to vintage effects, which were shown to be important in the United States since the early 1980s, leading to an underestimation of the growth of labor input (Bowlus anA1d Robinson, 2012). We apply their method for identifying vintage effects to a comparison between the United States and six European countries. We find that vintage effects led to increases of labor services per hour worked by high-skilled workers in the United States and United Kingdom and decreases in Continental European countries between 1995 and 2005. Rather than a productivity growth advantage of the US and UK, the primary difference with Continental European countries was human capital vintage effects instead. 相似文献
5.
The standard economy-wide indices of labour quality (or human capital) largely ignore the role of unobservable worker characteristics. In this article, we develop a methodology for identifying the contributions of both observable and unobservable worker characteristics in the presence of the incidental parameter problem. Based on data for Switzerland over the period 1991 to 2006, we find that a large part of growth in labour quality is caused by shifts in the distribution of unobservable worker characteristics. The overall index differs little from the standard indices, but contributions to growth attributed to education and age are corrected downwards. 相似文献
6.
Kevin James Bowman 《Economics of Innovation and New Technology》2013,22(6):571-592
A three-sector, overlapping-generations growth model endogenizes the opportunity cost of human capital formation and the relative skill requirements of invention, innovation, and adoption of general-purpose technologies. As a result, the relative wage of skilled workers is a function of the endogenous ratio of total-to-adoptive knowledge (where the difference in knowledge stocks is frontier knowledge). Comparative statics are examined for the model's seven parameters. Simulations (representing a transition with phases to a more complex level of economic development) are presented for simultaneous exogenous shocks capable of matching (i) observed inverse movements of the relative wage and the detrended relative supply in the USA, (ii) the sharp slowing and recovering US multifactor productivity growth data since the 1970s, and (iii) a reconciliation of data used to support or deny skill-biased technological change as a major force driving up the relative wage since 1980. 相似文献
7.
We examine whether affiliation in a multi-hospital system contributes to higher rates of total factor productivity (TFP) growth, technological progress and cost efficiency. With a 1996 to 1999 panel of 248 US hospitals (some are private nonprofit (church-related and other nonprofit) and the remaining are public (government, nonfederal)), empirical results indicate that urban system member hospitals experienced higher rates of both TFP growth and technical progress than the rates of TFP growth and technical progress experienced by urban nonsystem hospitals. Rural system member hospitals experienced smaller rates of both TFP decline and technical regress than the rates of TFP decline and technical regress experienced by rural nonsystem hospitals. 相似文献
8.
We develop an endogenous growth model in which skill acquisition by households and innovation by firms make distinct contributions to productivity growth. Nevertheless, the incentives faced by firms and households are inextricably linked because skills are required to implement new technologies. Skills and technologies are dynamic complements but, because their production complementarity is inherently bounded, they are equal partners in driving growth: neither can generate sustained growth alone. Our model has important implications for the effectiveness of alternative growth-promoting policies, for interpretating the empirical relationship between growth and schooling, and the relationship between growth and intergenerational wage dispersion. 相似文献
9.
In this article, we set out a model of labour productivity which distinguishes between shocks which change productivity permanently and shocks which have transient affects on productivity. We show that this model is a type of unobserved components model – a random walk with drift plus noise model. The advantage of this approach is that it provides a coherent framework to identify the deterministic trend growth component and also the productivity enhancing (or technology related) stochastic components. The model is applied to aggregate labour productivity in Australia and the time series of technology shocks extracted is used to shed some light on the contributions of policy reforms to productivity. 相似文献
10.
本文探讨了现代企业生产力管理中健康管理的作用,提出健康管理是2j世纪企业提升生产力的新战略,是提高健康资源效益的有效途径。企业对健康的投资是一种重要的人力资本投资,健康管理是现代企业全面提高竞争力的必要手段。 相似文献
11.
基于中国劳动力就业结构出现过快和过早去工业化的迹象,本文从部门间生产率差距的视角,利用多部门一般均衡模型、数值模拟和计量实证分析方法研究发现:(1)理论上,当服务业劳动生产率增长慢于工业,部门间生产率差距将扩大,导致劳动力去工业化速率加快;且部门间生产率差距的存在使得劳动力去工业化对经济增长产生结构性减速效应。服务业部门生产率加快提升,部门间生产率差距将会缩小,从而减缓去工业化速率和降低结构性减速压力;工业部门生产率提升尽管会扩大部门间生产率差距从而加快劳动力去工业化,但在长期中起到均匀化经济增长速率的作用。(2)利用2001—2018年中国省级和城市级面板数据的计量实证分析发现,部门间生产率差距的存在导致劳动力去工业化的效应在全时段样本下显著,但劳动力去工业化对经济增长的结构性减速效应仅在2009—2018年区间样本下显著,表明近年来中国经济增长减速与部门间生产率差距及其导致的劳动力去工业化相关。(3)赶超成功与失败国家的经验比较也表明,工业与服务业部门劳动生产率的改善与协调是跨越中等收入陷阱以及跨越后实现持续赶超的关键。 相似文献
12.
Charlotte Le Chapelain 《European Journal of the History of Economic Thought》2019,26(4):775-800
AbstractThe paper provides, a cliometric analysis on the impact of steam engine technology on the rise of adult education in nineteenth-century France. We exploit exogenous regional variations in the distribution of steam engines across France to evidence that technological change significantly contributed to the development of lifelong training during the 1850–1881 period. Our research shows that steam technology adoption in France was not deskilling. We argue that this process raised the demand for new skills adapted to the development of French industries. 相似文献
13.
Gaowen Kong 《Applied economics》2017,49(27):2655-2668
This article analyses the effects of corporate governance (CG) and human capital on productivity by using the 1999–2006 data from the National Bureau of Statistics of China (NBSC). The findings of this study are twofold. First, CG and human capital generate significant positive effects on the productivity of both state-owned enterprises (SOEs) and non-SOEs. Second, CG has significantly different moderate and mediate effects on the relationship between human capital and productivity. Our results are robust to different specifications and alternative measures. This study provides clear policy implications by suggesting that the firms in emerging markets, especially SOEs, must improve their CG and their allocation of human capital for them to enhance their productivity. 相似文献
14.
《Education Economics》2012,20(5):522-537
This paper examines the impact of education on economic growth in Greece over the period 1960–2000 by applying the model introduced by Mankiw, Romer, and Weil. The findings of the empirical analysis reveal that education had a positive and statistically significant effect on economic growth in Greece over the period 1960–2000. The econometric model explained up to 66% of the variation of the economic growth rate through the variation of the independent variables (physical capital, human capital, and labor). More specifically, when the coefficient of education is estimated using time lags, the contribution of the annual differences of human capital growth to the annual differences of GDP growth has been estimated from an annual 0.64% up to 0.81%. 相似文献
15.
在运用改进方法对我国省级人力资本存量和全要素生产率进行了再测算的基础上,引入地区技术差距变量,实证研究了1996—2016年间我国省级人力资本存量、地区技术差距对全要素生产率的影响。结果发现人力资本、地区技术差距对全要素生产率、技术效率改进、技术进步的作用,存在相互制约、互相促进的一个过程,这是对已有文献研究结论的一个补充。 相似文献
16.
知识经济时代,科技创新的难度不断加大,需要科技创新领军人物引领创新团队去实现创新目标。在分析科技创新领军人物人力资本分层的基础上,深入探究其人力资本存在的特征,提出作为高新技术的发明者、创新价值的实现者和持续创新的反哺者的科技创新领军人物人力资本创新效用。 相似文献
17.
Kenneth Carlaw 《Economics of Innovation and New Technology》2013,22(4):299-309
A dynamic general equilibrium model is constructed and used to identify sources of total factor productivity growth in Canada and to quantify their importance. The model also provides procedures for constructing measures of technological progress. We find that periods of low productivity growth correspond to periods of high growth in investment-specific technology (IST) or high rates of technology embodiment. For example, the growth rate of IST was relatively high between 1974 and 1996. The higher growth rate of IST during this period should have increased the rate of productivity growth by an estimated 0.29 percentage points, ceteris paribus. Yet, productivity growth slowed. Why? 相似文献
18.
用非参数生产前沿方法将我国1978-2007年工业劳动生产率增长分解为效率变化、技术变化、物质资本和人力资本变化的贡献四个部分,并用方差分解方法估算了各部分对地区工业劳动生产率增长差异的贡献,然后采用核密度分布方法分析了上述四个部分对工业劳动生产率差距以及三次产业对地区收入差距的影响。研究发现:(1)物质资本积累是我国工业劳动生产率增长和地区差距的主要来源,人力资本积累的贡献较小;(2)效率虽然对工业劳动生产率增长的贡献较小,但却是工业劳动生产率地区差异的重要原因;(3)技术是要素非中性的,且技术进步主要发生在有效劳均资本较高的地区。(4)1978-1992年期间,地区收入差距主要来自农业劳动生产率增长差异,而在1992-2007年期间,地区收入差距则主要来自工业劳动生产率增长差异。 相似文献
19.
Dirk Frantzen 《The Scandinavian journal of economics》2000,102(1):57-75
This paper is based on recent developments in the theory of innovation-driven growth that emphasize both the importance of R&D efforts — domestic as well as foreign — for explaining national productivity, and the complementarity between R&D and human capital investments. Estimates of specifications, in growth terms and in level terms, on a cross-section of OECD countries from the early 1960s to the early 1990s lend strong support to this thesis. The data show a significant influence of both domestic and foreign R&D. Moreover, there is clearly a net positive impact of human capital. The level and growth rate of human capital are shown to affect productivity growth and there is evidence of interaction with the catch-up process.
JEL classification: O 33; O 47 相似文献
JEL classification: O 33; O 47 相似文献
20.
技术模仿、人力资本积累与自主创新——基于中国省际面板数据的实证分析 总被引:4,自引:0,他引:4
文章选取我国1996~2004年的省际面板数据,运用门槛效应(threshold efhct)分析方法,从人力资本积累角度,探讨适宜我国当前经济增长的技术进步途径。实证表明,FDI的资本积累效应与R&D投入已对我国现实经济的发展作出显著贡献;我国现有整体人力资本已达到进行有效技术模仿的临界值,技术模仿对我国经济的贡献已凸显出来,但同时也存在区域差异;而我国现有人力资本尚未满足全面自主创新的要求,加大人力资本积累是我国实施全面自主创新战略的重要支撑。 相似文献