共查询到20条相似文献,搜索用时 15 毫秒
1.
Luca Benzoni Pierre Collin-Dufresne Robert S. Goldstein 《Journal of Financial Economics》2011,101(3):552-573
The 1987 market crash was associated with a dramatic and permanent steepening of the implied volatility curve for equity index options, despite minimal changes in aggregate consumption. We explain these events within a general equilibrium framework in which expected endowment growth and economic uncertainty are subject to rare jumps. The arrival of a jump triggers the updating of agents' beliefs about the likelihood of future jumps, which produces a market crash and a permanent shift in option prices. Consumption and dividends remain smooth, and the model is consistent with salient features of individual stock options, equity returns, and interest rates. 相似文献
2.
Panayiotis C. Andreou 《Quantitative Finance》2013,13(12):2021-2040
We investigate the relative importance of market default risk in explaining the time variation of the S&P 500 Index option-implied risk-neutral moments. The results demonstrate that market default risk is positively (negatively) related to the index risk-neutral volatility and skewness (kurtosis). These relations are robust in the presence of other factors relevant to the dynamics and microstructure nature of the spot and option markets. Overall, this study sheds light on a set of economic determinants which help to understand the daily evolution of the S&P 500 Index option-implied risk-neutral distributions. Our findings offer explanations of why theoretical predictions of option pricing models are not consistent with what is observed in practice and provide support that market default risk is important to asset pricing. 相似文献
3.
This study explores the effect of investor sentiment on the volatility forecasting power of option-implied information. We find that the risk-neutral skewness has the explanatory power regarding future volatility only during high sentiment periods. Furthermore, the implied volatility has varying volatility forecasting ability depending on the level of investor sentiment. Our findings suggest that the effectiveness of volatility forecasting models based on option-implied information varies over time with the level of investor sentiment. We confirm the important role of investor sentiment in volatility forecasting models exploiting option-implied information with strong evidence from in-sample and out-of-sample analyses. We also present improvements in the accuracy of volatility forecasts from volatility forecasting models derived by incorporating investor sentiment in these models. 相似文献
4.
Ryan McCrickerd 《Quantitative Finance》2013,13(11):1877-1886
The rough Bergomi model, introduced by Bayer et al. [Quant. Finance, 2016, 16(6), 887–904], is one of the recent rough volatility models that are consistent with the stylised fact of implied volatility surfaces being essentially time-invariant, and are able to capture the term structure of skew observed in equity markets. In the absence of analytical European option pricing methods for the model, we focus on reducing the runtime-adjusted variance of Monte Carlo implied volatilities, thereby contributing to the model’s calibration by simulation. We employ a novel composition of variance reduction methods, immediately applicable to any conditionally log-normal stochastic volatility model. Assuming one targets implied volatility estimates with a given degree of confidence, thus calibration RMSE, the results we demonstrate equate to significant runtime reductions—roughly 20 times on average, across different correlation regimes. 相似文献
5.
AbstractGiven bid-offer quotes for a set of listed vanilla options, a fundamental need of option market makers is to interpolate and extrapolate the available quotes to a full arbitrage-free surface. We propose a methodology which directly controls the trade-off between smoothness and bid-offer compliance of the resulting volatility surface. Unlike previous literature, the method applies simultaneously to all listed maturities and aims to smooth the implied risk-neutral densities. Additionally, we consider asset dynamics which allow for general dividend streams—continuous, discrete yield and discrete cash—a modelling aspect of key importance in option markets. 相似文献
6.
In this paper, we analyze properties of multinomial lattices that model general stochastic dynamics of the underlying stock by taking into account any given cumulants (or moments). First, we provide a parameterization of multinomial lattices, and demonstrate that mean, variance, skewness, and kurtosis of the underlying may be matched using five branches. Then, we investigate the convergence of the multinomial lattice when the basic time period approaches zero, and prove that the limiting process of the multinomial lattice that matches annualized mean, variance, skewness and kurtosis is given by a compound Poisson process. Finally, we illustrate the effect of higher order moments in the underlying asset process on the price of derivative securities through numerical experiments using the multinomial lattice, and provide a comparison with jump-diffusion models. 相似文献
7.
We develop a new approach for pricing European-style contingent claims written on the time T spot price of an underlying asset whose volatility is stochastic. Like most of the stochastic volatility literature, we assume
continuous dynamics for the price of the underlying asset. In contrast to most of the stochastic volatility literature, we
do not directly model the dynamics of the instantaneous volatility. Instead, taking advantage of the recent rise of the variance
swap market, we directly assume continuous dynamics for the time T variance swap rate. The initial value of this variance swap rate can either be directly observed, or inferred from option
prices. We make no assumption concerning the real world drift of this process. We assume that the ratio of the volatility
of the variance swap rate to the instantaneous volatility of the underlying asset just depends on the variance swap rate and
on the variance swap maturity. Since this ratio is assumed to be independent of calendar time, we term this key assumption
the stationary volatility ratio hypothesis (SVRH). The instantaneous volatility of the futures follows an unspecified stochastic
process, so both the underlying futures price and the variance swap rate have unspecified stochastic volatility. Despite this,
we show that the payoff to a path-independent contingent claim can be perfectly replicated by dynamic trading in futures contracts
and variance swaps of the same maturity. As a result, the contingent claim is uniquely valued relative to its underlying’s
futures price and the assumed observable variance swap rate. In contrast to standard models of stochastic volatility, our
approach does not require specifying the market price of volatility risk or observing the initial level of instantaneous volatility.
As a consequence of our SVRH, the partial differential equation (PDE) governing the arbitrage-free value of the contingent
claim just depends on two state variables rather than the usual three. We then focus on the consistency of our SVRH with the
standard assumption that the risk-neutral process for the instantaneous variance is a diffusion whose coefficients are independent
of the variance swap maturity. We show that the combination of this maturity independent diffusion hypothesis (MIDH) and our
SVRH implies a very special form of the risk-neutral diffusion process for the instantaneous variance. Fortunately, this process
is tractable, well-behaved, and enjoys empirical support. Finally, we show that our model can also be used to robustly price
and hedge volatility derivatives. 相似文献
8.
9.
Mireille Bossy Rajna Gibson Francois-Serge Lhabitant Nathalie Pistre Denis Talay 《Review of Derivatives Research》2006,9(2):109-135
In this paper, we analyse the model misspecification risk of Markovian hedging strategies for discount bond options. We show how to decompose the Profit and Loss that results from model misspecification, and emphasize the importance of the position’s gamma in order to control it. We further provide mathematical results on the distribution of the forward Profit and Loss function for specific univariate term structure models. Finally, we run numerical simulations for options’ hedging strategies in order to examine the sensitivity of the forward Profit and Loss function with respect to the volatility of the forward rate curve, the frequency of the position rebalancing and the characteristics of the position being hedged. 相似文献
10.
We study the cross-sectional performance of option pricing models in which the volatility of the underlying stock is a deterministic function of the stock price and time. For each date in our sample of FTSE 100 index option prices, we fit an implied binomial tree to the panel of all European style options with different strike prices and maturities and then examine how well this model prices a corresponding panel of American style options. We find that the implied binomial tree model performs no better than an ad-hoc procedure of smoothing Black–Scholes implied volatilities across strike prices and maturities. Our cross-sectional results complement the time-series findings of Dumas et al. [J. Finance 53 (1998) 2059]. 相似文献
11.
We seek to reconcile the debate about the price effect of risk-neutral skewness (RNS) on stocks. We document positive predictability from short-term skewness, consistent with informed-trading demand, and negative predictability from long-term skewness, consistent with skewness preference. A term spread on RNS captures different information from long- and short-term contracts, resulting in stronger predictability. The quintile portfolio with the lowest spread outperforms that with highest spread by 14.64% annually. The term structure of RNS predicts earnings surprises and price crashes. We extract the slope factor from RNS term structure, estimate its risk premium, and explore its relation with several macroeconomic variables. 相似文献
12.
This paper presents a closed-form solution for the valuation of European options under the assumption that the excess returns of an underlying asset follow a diffusion process. In light of our model, the implied volatility computed from the Black–Scholes formula should be viewed as the volatility of excess returns rather than as the volatility of gross returns. Using the SPX and the OMX options data, we test whether implied volatility obtained from Black-Scholes option price explains the volatilities of excess returns better than gross returns, even though the result is not statistically significant. 相似文献
13.
This paper examines the behaviour of the smile in the Spanish Stock Exchange during 2011 and 2012 summers. In these periods, the value of the main index of the Spanish Stock Exchange market IBEX-35 had fallen down a maximum of 2103.60 points in summer 2011, which made a drop of 20.05% in this period. On the contrary, in summer 2012, it had raised a maximum of 2165.70 points. That means a rise of 26.31%, whereas the Spanish risk premium had raised dramatically. By linear interpolation, implied volatilities for moneyness points needed were calculated. Then, we construct 3288 smile curves and the same quantity of distortion levels. Thousand six hundred and forty-four smiles are for both call and put option contracts, and for all summer 2011 and 2012 maturities (June, July, August and September). Next, we compare all smile curves with 1 of the 17-typical shape patterns for calls, puts, different dates, etc. Afterwards, we take the value of the distortion level calculated before and include the smile in one A–E class of distortion. We can notice that the most popular types are only two, for both calls and puts, Left Smirk (LK) rather than Reversed Right Smirk (RRK); all smiles are formed in the same way, and they are all from ‘D’ class. The changes between LK and RRK occur only on, or one day after, expiring dates, thus are jumps in distortion. Afterwards, we make a comparison with 2013 and 2014 summers' smiles which are not marred by the short-selling ban imposed by the Spanish Securities Exchange Commission in 2011 and 2012. 相似文献
14.
We develop a discrete-time stochastic volatility option pricing model exploiting the information contained in the Realized Volatility (RV), which is used as a proxy of the unobservable log-return volatility. We model the RV dynamics by a simple and effective long-memory process, whose parameters can be easily estimated using historical data. Assuming an exponentially affine stochastic discount factor, we obtain a fully analytic change of measure. An empirical analysis of Standard and Poor's 500 index options illustrates that our model outperforms competing time-varying and stochastic volatility option pricing models. 相似文献
15.
Johnson R. Pawlukiewicz JAMES Mehta JAYESH 《Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting》1997,9(1):89-101
This research presents a method for estimating the parameters of the binomial option pricing model necessary to appropriately price calls on assets with asymmetric end-of-period return distributions. Parameters of the binomial model are shown to be a function of the mean, variance, and skewness of the underlying return distribution. It is also shown that failure to incorporate skewness results in the mispricing of the call. 相似文献
16.
Implied standard deviation is widely believed to be the best available forecast of the volatility of returns over the remaining contract life (Jorion, 1995 ). In this paper, we take this result two steps further to the higher moments of the distribution (skewness and kurtosis) based on a Gram–Charlier series expansion of the normal distribution (Corrado and Su, 1996 ) using long-term CAC 40 option prices contract, named PXL. First, we found that implied first moments contain a substantial amount of information for future moments of CAC 40 returns although this amount decreases with respect to the moment's order. Secondly, we found that the different shapes of the volatility smile are consistent with different distribution of the underlying returns. Based on these results, we also observed that including other implied moments significantly improves the out-of-sample pricing performance of the Black–Scholes, (1973) model. 相似文献
17.
Samuel Ze‐To 《Accounting & Finance》2016,56(4):1187-1214
I derive the option‐implied volatility allowing for nonzero correlation between price jump and diffusive risk to examine the information content of implied diffusive, jump risks and their implied covariance in the cross‐sectional variation of future returns. This study documents a strong predictive power of realized volatility and correlated implied volatility spread (RV ? IVC) in the cross section of stock returns. The difference of realized volatility with the implied diffusive volatility (RV ? σC), jump risk (RV ? γC) and covariance (RV ? ICov) can forecast future returns. These RV ? σC and RV ? γC anomalies are robustly persistent even after controlling for market, size, book‐to‐market value, momentum and liquidity factors. 相似文献
18.
Standard delta hedging fails to exactly replicate a European call option in the presence of transaction costs. We study a pricing and hedging model similar to the delta hedging strategy with an endogenous volatility parameter for the calculation of delta over time. The endogenous volatility depends on both the transaction costs and the option strike prices. The optimal hedging volatility is calculated using the criterion of minimizing the weighted upside and downside replication errors. The endogenous volatility model with equal weights on the up and down replication errors yields an option premium close to the Leland [J. Finance, 1985, 40, 1283–1301] heuristic approach. The model with weights being the probabilities of the option's moneyness provides option prices closest to the actual prices. Option prices from the model are identical to the Black–Scholes option prices when transaction costs are zero. Data on S&P 500 index cash options from January to June 2008 illustrate the model. 相似文献
19.
Option prices tend to be correlated to past stock market returns due to market imperfections. We unprecedentedly examine this issue on the SSE 50 ETF option in the Chinese derivatives market. To measure the price pressure in the options market, we construct an implied volatility spread based on pairs of the SSE 50 ETF option with identical expiration dates and strike prices. By regressing the implied volatility spread on past stock returns, we find that past stock returns exert a strong influence on the pricing of index options. Specifically, we find that SSE 50 ETF calls are significantly overvalued relative to SSE 50 ETF puts after stock price increases and the reverse is also true after the stock price decreases. Moreover, we validate the momentum effects in the underlying stock market to be responsible for the price pressure. These findings are both economically and statistically significant and have important implications. 相似文献
20.
Anlong Li 《European Financial Management》1999,5(2):203-222
The common practice of using different volatilities for options of different strikes in the Black-Scholes (1973) model imposes inconsistent assumptions on underlying securities. The phenomenon is referred to as the volatility smile. This paper addresses this problem by replacing the Brownian motion or, alternatively, the Geometric Brownian motion in the Black-Scholes model with a two-piece quadratic or linear function of the Brownian motion. By selecting appropriate parameters of this function we obtain a wide range of shapes of implied volatility curves with respect to option strikes. The model has closed-form solutions for European options, which enables fast calibration of the model to market option prices. The model can also be efficiently implemented in discrete time for pricing complex options.
G1 相似文献
G1 相似文献