首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
相似文献
 共查询到20条相似文献,搜索用时 31 毫秒
1.
Economic theory suggests that some of the trade remedies allowed by the WTO may lead away from liberal trade and impose costs on those that apply them. Breuss has provided evidence in the case of four EU-US mini-wars that the policy that created the trade conflict was not clearly in the economic interest of the offending country and that the sanctions imposed exacerbated rather than alleviated the problem. Breuss builds a case for compensation payments rather than trade sanctions for rule violations and for targeting of the recipients of those payments.If trade policy were a matter of economic rationality then this approach would be convincing. For better or worse, the trade rules are an unruly mix of economic, political and legal constructs. The commentary expands on this to explore the role of the dispute settlement process itself and the sanctions designed to give it teeth. The conclusion is that the economic calculations, while a good measure of the costs of legal or political decisions, are not central to the dispute settlement and sanctions processes. The dispute settlement process is also about preserving the balance of political advantage from negotiated rules and schedules, and the sanctions process is as much to do with preventing abuse as correcting it. So a full economic analysis would have to compare politically balanced alternative scenarios and the incorporate the effect of the threat of sanctions on government behavior.  相似文献   

2.
中美纺织品贸易一直摩擦不断,先是20世纪80年代的反倾销,后是90年代多次单方面扣减中方纺织品配额,进入21世纪,美国除连续对中国纺织品实施特保措施外,还同时使用反倾销措施.根据中美纺织品贸易摩擦所呈现出的阶段性特点,可以确定政治考量是美对华纺织品实施限制的路径选择的主要依据.  相似文献   

3.
中美纺织品贸易摩擦原因分析与思考   总被引:5,自引:0,他引:5  
中美纺织品贸易摩擦发生的原因在于:(1)加入、WTO后,中国部分纺织品对美国出口增加使美国的一些厂商利益受到影响:(2)中美贸易不平衡的扩大增加了美国对中国出口增长的不满情绪:(3)美国国内政治因素诱发了中美纺织品贸易摩擦的发生。此次贸易摩擦的发生不仅会使中国生产者遭受损失,也会给美国带来损害。  相似文献   

4.
This paper explores the commitment to corporate citizenship on the part of the largest U.S.-based multinationals in the emerging market region of Latin America. The websites of the largest U.S.-based firms – according to the 2007 Fortune 500 list – are reviewed and their CSR efforts in Latin America are noted. The firms’ positions on corporate citizenship in Latin America are mapped onto a three-by-three matrix in which firms’ commitment to corporate citizenship ranges from profit-making motivations to a more holistic approach where support for non-profit causes is embraced by the entire firm and implemented at all levels (Marsden, Business and Society Review 105(1), 9–26, 2000). The largest U.S.-based multinationals were selected for this study because of their leadership role and the fact that other firms within their respective industries may seek to emulate the firms’ level of commitment to corporate citizenship. While the matrix can be used to evaluate corporate citizenship efforts in any market – or globally – the emphasis in this study is on Latin America, a region of interest for two reasons: because of the paucity of research on this particular emerging market region as it relates to CSR, and because there is some evidence to suggest that philanthropic initiatives by the region’s wealthy individuals lag behind individual philanthropic efforts in other world regions (Oppenheimer, Latin America’s Rich Should Donate More. McClatchey-Tribune Regional News, 2007). If this is the case, this study aims to identify whether companies are picking up the slack.
“You make a living by what you get; but you make a life by what you give.” Winston Churchill
  相似文献   

5.
If you are considering to trade with companies in Japan or expanding your .business to Japan, we are ready to help from the very beginning." You will find this greeting at the first sight on the Chinese website of Japan External Trade Organization (JETRO). JETRO has committed itself in delivering highly efficient and quality services to meet the demand of internal and external customs including Japanese companies, hence winning a good reputation in the international trade arena. In recent years, with its priority in advancing business cooperation in South and East Asia, JETRO has made great achievement in promoting trade between China and Japan. Therefore, China's Foreign Trade interviewed Mr. Yoichi Maine, Deputy Director General of JETRO BEIJING.  相似文献   

6.
Fundamental Rights and the European Regulation of iConsumer Contracts   总被引:1,自引:1,他引:0  
This paper addresses the question of how fundamental rights affect European legislation and adjudication on contracts regarding digital information services (iConsumer contracts). Fundamental rights may be seen as representing political choices for the protection of certain values in society, but at the same time, they are enacted rules of the legal system, which may be invoked to enforce the protection of the interests they represent. It is submitted that because of this double-faced nature, they can bring to the fore policy issues in contract legislation and case law. Fundamental rights can thus play a role in evaluating the policy choices that are being made in the review of the acquis communautaire in the field of consumer law. For iConsumer contracts, that means that the rights of consumers, authors, and suppliers of copyright-protected content affect the choice of rule-solutions on the European legislative level. Furthermore, these rights have an impact on the case law of the European Court of Justice in the field of e-commerce. Fundamental rights help define the various rule-solutions the Court can choose from and thus demarcate the law-making capacity of the judiciary.
Chantal MakEmail:
  相似文献   

7.
《美韩自由贸易协定》是近年来美国与贸易伙伴间所达成的最具经济重要性和影响力的一项优惠贸易安排,中国亦是该协定的重要"利益攸关方",尤其在纺织品服装领域。本文在对该协定的纺织品条款进行全面分析的基础上,就协定实施后对中国输美纺织品服装的贸易影响进行了初步定量评估。评估主要基于2005~2010年数据,从中韩两国输美产品总体结构相似度和具体产品类别的贸易替代价格弹性两方面展开。  相似文献   

8.
Theoretical models of negotiation and group decision making often overlook or at least do not fully account for the important role played by persons who advise negotiators and participants in group decision making. Sight unseen, advisors are often “hidden persuaders,” important but unrecognized sources of influence on the negotiation dynamic. This article explores the roles and methods of advisors in the negotiation process, drawing on survey research conducted in 2013 among approximately seventy advisors at the European Union Council of Ministers. Defining advice as “\(\ldots \)a communication from one person (the advisor) to another (the client) for the purpose of helping that second person determine a course of action for solving a particular problem\(\ldots \)”, the author considers the nature of advice and the range of relationships that may exist between advisors and their clients. He argues that advising is much more than the mere transmittal of information from advisor to negotiator and that for advice to be effective a relationship must exist between the two parties. The author identifies three models of the advisor–negotiator relationship. Model I is the advisor as director, wherein the advisor tends to take control of the negotiating process, directing the negotiator in actions that the negotiator should take to achieve success at the negotiation. Model II is the advisor as servant in which the advisor merely responds to the demands of the client for help and guidance in the negotiation. Model III is the advisor as partner, wherein advisor and negotiator jointly manage the advising process and together take co-ownership of the problem to be solved. The author then explores the factors that lead advisors and negotiators to adopt each of these three models, the various advising styles that advisors adopt, and the differing effects on the negotiation process that these elements may have, drawing on historical examples as well as survey data from the EU Council of Ministers. He concludes by offering advice about advising to three important professional groups—scholars, negotiators, and advisors—on ways to carry out their respective functions more effectively.  相似文献   

9.
One of the main objectives in the information society is to improve the quality of life. — Paying attention to the needs of people seems to be a key element in good ethical behaviour, says Tor Dahl, Managing Director of Manpower Scandinavia. In defining these needs, Manpower used Abraham Maslow's famous pyramid, his hierarchy of needs, as a model for trying to satisfy in practise the needs on each level. However, they went a step further, asking; what comes after Maslow? To mean something for others; togetherness and that people can be trusted and that they seek a purpose with their work, came out as answers. In his paper Mr. Dahl tells us how Manpower Scandinavia has developed a written set of values, which function as a basis for action and guidelines for behaviour, and where the key idea behind it all is to let people be self-managed. Furthermore, he shows us how Manpower has organised the company according to this conviction. — If your really have faith in people and show them trust, they will show you trust in return. Then you have a good basis for ethical behaviour, Tor Dahl concludes his paper.  相似文献   

10.
Based on the theory of technology spillover in international trade, this paper discusses the technological innovation effect of trade by taking the influence of domestic trade into account. Under the constraint of the production possibility frontier, there is either complementarity or substitutability between domestic and foreign trade. It must be decided whether resources should be concentrated in one of the sectors (trade specialization) or instead allocated equally (trade equalization) between the two sectors. This paper firstly discusses how domestic trade and foreign trade work together to influence technological innovation, and how trade equalization and specialization affect different types of innovation. Using a provincial-level panel dataset from 2007 to 2015 in China, this paper constructs the indicators of domestic and foreign trade linkage and examines the impact of trade on innovation. The findings show that trade equalization mainly promotes incremental innovation, while trade specialization improves radical innovation. Thus, in the area of incremental innovation, attention should be paid to the equalized development of domestic and foreign trade, while in areas pursuing radical innovation, emphasis should be put on the specialization of the trade sector, avoiding equal allocation of resources to the two sectors.  相似文献   

11.
The lyrics below are mine but the tune is “Sgt. Pepper's Lonely Hearts Club Band.” Though you may have been born after this song hit the airwaves, this Beatles standard should be one of those melodies that is indelibly etched in your mind … so sing, and sing it loud:
相似文献   

12.
In this article we integrate two topics in international trade policy that have received (separately) a lot of attention: the effects of regional trade blocs, and export pessimism regarding poorer countries. The specific issue that allows us to bring together these questions is whether regional integration adversely affects non-members. We use quarterly data on bilateral trade flows for the period 1990 through 1997 to examine U.S. imports from its NAFTA partners as well as from non-NAFTA trade partners, and more specifically, those countries expected to be hurt by NAFTA. Two measures are used:
  1. “import penetration” or imports from a particular source as a share of US GDP, and

  2. the income elasticity of expenditure on imports from a particular source. Both “import penetration” and the income elasticity of expenditure affect the export earnings of U.S. trade partners, a matter of particular concern for developing countries.

The broadest pattern observed in the income-expenditure elasticities is clear evidence of increased penetration by non-oil developing countries. This is in marked contrast to the stable GDP share and expenditure elasticity for developed country imports. Regional results suggest that the Caribbean and the East Asian NICs were the only area groupings that experienced a reduction in income-expenditure elasticity. But overall on the basis of U.S. income-expenditure elasticities it appears that the first four years of NAFTA were associated with trade expansion rather than trade diversion.  相似文献   

13.
14.
In this paper, the author replies to Bish, McKean, Offe, Stevens, and Bull, concerning his original paper Consumer Problems in the Public Sector, JCP, 1, 1977/3. The reply elaborates on the concepts of tax-price, political and organizational failures, and the relationships of these failure modes to public sector consumer problems. The present paper also develops a more explicit classification of public sector consumers, and it relates the discussion of public sector consumer problems to branches of the literature concerned with fiscal illusion and consumption costs.
Verbraucherprobleme im Bereich öffentlicher Leistungen: Eine Antwort auf die Stellungnahmen von Bish, McKean, Offe, Stevens und Bull
Zusammenfassung Die Antwort klärt und verteidigt die Verwendung des Steuer-Preis-Konzepts bei der Ableitung von Unzulänglichkeiten einerseits im Bereich der politischen Willensbildung und andererseits im Bereich der Bürokratie, aus denen im ersten Beitrag des Autors seine Systematik von Verbraucherproblemen bei öffentlichen Leistungen abgeleitet wurde. Die Antwort arbeitet schärfer die Unterschiede und Wechselbeziehungen zwischen den beiden Arten von Unzulänglichkeiten und ihre Beziehungen zu einzelnen Verbraucherproblemen heraus. Darüber hinaus entwickelt sie eine Klassifikation von Verbrauchern öffentlicher Leistungen, behandelt die Unterschiede von Verbraucherproblemen und allgemein gesellschaftlichen Problemen und diskutiert kurz, durch welche institutionellen Reformen öffentliche Anlaufstellen für Verbraucherprobleme geschaffen werden können. Schließlich zeigt die Stellungnahme einige Linien für die Weiterentwicklung der Forschung im Bereich von Verbraucherproblemen bei öffentlichen Leistungen auf.


Dennis R. Young is an Associate Professor at the W. Averell Harriman College for Urban and Policy Sciences, State University of New York at Stony Brook, Stony Brook, New York 11794, U.S.A. He is grateful to Professor John Russell of the Germanic and Slavic Languages Department at Stony Brook, for his translation of Hans Peter Bull's comments from German to English, and to Professor Richard Silkman of the Harriman College at Stony Brook for his suggestions on this reply.  相似文献   

15.
随着2021年的到来,我们每一个人都迫切需要新的开始,这意味着希望也随之而来。无论是准备一个活动,会议或贸易展,现在是时候重新调整你的规划过程了,并把清洁,健康和安全纳入管理规定之中,科学的防疫规定让你能更好的掌舵你的活动。  相似文献   

16.
17.
Controlling firms’ sales in the labour demand model, this paper investigates effects of trade and R&D via technical progress on labour demand in a dynamic framework, based on a panel of Swedish manufacturing firms for 1990s. The main results of this study indicate that employment elasticities with respect to different characteristics of firms (wages, total sales, exports and R&D efforts) and industrial import penetration could vary across respective skilled sectors. There is some indication to that import penetration from fourteen ‘old members’ of European Union could induce capital-saving technical progress and result in the rise in demand for labour for firms in medium-low skilled sector, whilst those from the ten ‘new members’ of European Union could induce x-efficiency and labour-saving technical progress for firms in low-skilled sector. Furthermore, the effects of R&D intensity on demand for labour are positive and significant for firms in medium-high-skilled and high-skilled sectors.
Lihong YunEmail:
  相似文献   

18.
In order to enrich global corporate culture, a distinction must be made between the economic ideology of free trade and the moral ideology of fair trade. GATT has failed to make this distinction. Its sole ethos of free trade is only applicable among developmentally equivalent nations, and has been used by TNCs as a means for attaining their commercial ends in the third world. GATT's lack of commitment to an objective of fair trade necessitates its replacement. This article suggests a replacement in the form of a network of trade organizations. The network takes the form of a hub-and-spoke arrangement, in which the hub would be the Global Trade Organization, and the spokes would each represent Regional Trade Organizations.John Dobson is currently an Associate Professor of Finance at California Polytechnic State University in San Luis Obispo. His primary research interests are Agency Theory and Financial Ethics. His publications include articles and letters inJournal of Business Ethics, Financial Management, Business in the Contemporary World andBusiness and Society.  相似文献   

19.
This paper develops and estimates a structural model of imperfect competition in international markets. The model incorporates a flexible non-linear demand framework with structural price equations. A general Conjectural Variation approach is developed to characterize strategic interaction. This allows the simultaneous evaluation of the sector-specific terms of trade effects of a Preferential Trade Agreement (PTA), and the extent of international competition in the sector under consideration. The model is then used to evaluate the impact of the Lebanese–Egyptian PTA on the iron and steel import sector in Lebanon. Results confirm the need for a structural approach in the empirical assessment of PTAs.
Alban Thomas (Corresponding author)Email:
  相似文献   

20.
The generalized aggregated trade models do not capture the industry or product‐specific competitive situation and overgeneralize the bilateral cases. As a result, product‐specific trade determinants at the sectoral or bilateral level cannot be sufficiently drawn from such generalized models. This holds true for knitwear clothing products, an important component of international textile trade. To remedy this, we propose a sector‐specific bilateral model in the context of knitwear clothing exports from India to the United States. This pair of countries is chosen due to unilateral trade flows as well as to underline the contrasting features of developed north versus developing south. The vector autoregression (VAR) model was found more appropriate than other available modeling choices. We used monthly frequency data from January 2006 to December 2012. The traditional determinants such as exchange rate and price competitiveness remain relevant. Chinese competition emerges as a significant determinant, which underlines the relevance of a sector‐specific bilateral trade model. The 2009 recession showed a clear impact, albeit for only a few months. Our model is parsimonious but has more explanatory power than generalized models. Policy researchers may further explore the model for more fine‐tuned policy on sector‐specific factors. © 2016 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.  相似文献   

设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号