首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
相似文献
 共查询到20条相似文献,搜索用时 15 毫秒
1.
This article provides further evidence on the positive impact of schooling on within-groups wage dispersion in Portugal, using data on male workers from the 2001 wave of the European Community Household Panel. The issue of schooling endogeneity is taken into account by using the latest available instrumental-variable technique for quantile regression, i.e. the control-function estimator due to Lee (2007 Lee, S. 2007. Endogeneity in quantile regresssion models: a control function approach. Journal of Econometrics, 141: 113158. [Crossref], [Web of Science ®] [Google Scholar]). The findings are compared with earlier results based on different techniques, i.e. the instrumental-variable estimator due to Arias et al. (2001 Arias, O, Hallock, KF and Sosa-Escudero, W. 2001. Individual heterogeneity in the returns to schooling: instrumental variables quantile regression using twins data. Empirical Economics, 26: 740. [Crossref] [Google Scholar]) and the standard exogeneity-based estimator due to Koenker and Bassett (1978 Koenker, R and Bassett, G. 1978. Regression quantiles. Econometrica, 46: 3350. [Crossref], [Web of Science ®] [Google Scholar]).  相似文献   

2.
A. Dupuy 《Applied economics》2013,45(21):2723-2731
While the skill-premium has been rising sharply in the US and the UK for 20 years, the Dutch skill-premium decreased for much of that period and only started to rise in the early 90s. In this article, we investigate whether the Dutch skill-premium will rise in the next decades. To answer this question, we forecast the skill-premium using the Katz and Murphy (1992 Katz, L and Murphy, K. 1992. Changes in relative wages, 1963–1987: supply and demand factors. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107: 3578. [Crossref], [Web of Science ®] [Google Scholar]) and the Krusell et al. (2000 Krusell, P, Ohanian, L, Ríos-Rull, J-V and Violante, G. 2000. Capital-skill complementarity and inequality: a macroeconomic analysis. Econometrica, 68: 102953. [Crossref], [Web of Science ®] [Google Scholar]) models. The Katz and Murphy model (KM) explains demand shifts by skill-biased technological change in unobservable variables captured by a time trend. In contrast, the Krusell et al. model (KORV) explains demand shifts by (observable) changes in the capital stock under a capital-skill complementarity technology. The results show that while the KM model predicts that the skill-premium will have increased by 30% in 2020, based on realistic predictions of the stock of capital, the KORV model predicts that the skill-premium will remain between ?5 and +5% of its 1996 level.  相似文献   

3.
In this article we examine the persistence nature of Taiwan's aggregate output fluctuations by using the ‘innovation regime-switching’ (IRS) model in which the effect of an innovation may be permanent or transitory, depending on an unobservable state variable that follows a first order Markov chain. By applying the IRS model to Taiwan's real GDP data, we find that during the 1961 to 2000 period 61% (39%) of the real output shocks are likely to have permanent (transitory) effects. Moreover, the innovations in the officially identified expansion (contraction) are more likely to have a permanent (transitory) effect. These results are similar to those found in many studies of US real output fluctuations, e.g. Beaudry and Koop (1993 Beaudry, P and Koop, G. 1993. Do recessions permanently change output?. Journal of Monetary Economics, 31: 14963. [Crossref], [Web of Science ®] [Google Scholar]), Kim and Nelson (1999 Kim, C-J and Nelson, CR. 1999. Friedman's plucking model of business fluctuations: tests and estimates of permanent and transitory components. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 31: 31734.  [Google Scholar]) and Kuan et al. (2005 Kuan, C-M, Huang, Y-L and Tsay, RS. 2005. An unobserved component model with switching permanent and transitory innovations. Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, 23: 44354. [Taylor &; Francis Online], [Web of Science ®] [Google Scholar]). However, we also find that Taiwan's output dynamics have changed drastically ever since year 2000. In particular, the shocks to real GDP have become more likely to have only transitory effect, even during the period of post-2001:IV expansion.  相似文献   

4.
The aim of this paper is to develop a theoretical framework for the study and integration of financial innovation in the institutional structures that support the operation of the monetary system. The background of the analysis comes from original institutional economics (Bush and Tool 2003 Bush, Paul Dale and Marc R. Tool. “Foundational Concepts for Institutionalist Policy Making.” In Institutional Analysis and Economic Policy, edited by Paul D. Bush and Marc R. Tool, pp. 146. Dordrecht, Germany: Kluwer Academic Publishers, 2003.[Crossref] [Google Scholar]; Foster [1942] 1981 Foster, J. Fagg. “John Dewey and Economic Value.” Journal of Economic Issues 15, 4 ([1942] 1981): 871879. [Google Scholar], [1949] 1981 Foster, J. Fagg. “The Relation Between Theory of Value and Economic Analysis.” Journal of Economic Issues 15, 4 ([1949] 1981): 899905. [Google Scholar]; Veblen [1914] 1964 Veblen, Thorstein. The Instinct of Workmanship and the State of the Industrial Arts. New York, NY: Augustus M. Kelley, [1914] 1964. [Google Scholar], [1889] 1996 Veblen, Thorstein. The Theory of the Leisure Clash. London: Dover, [1889] 1996. [Google Scholar]), the state theory of money (Ingham 2004 Ingham, Geoffrey. The Nature of Money. London: Polity, 2004. [Google Scholar]; Papadopoulos 2009 Papadopoulos, Georgios. “Between Rules and Power: Money as an Institution Sanctioned by Political Authority.” Journal of Economic Issues 43, 4 (2009): 951969.[Taylor &; Francis Online] [Google Scholar]), and a specific account of social ontology based on constitutive and normative rules as well as the notion of collective intentionality (Searle 2005 Searle, John. “What Is an Institution?” Journal of Institutional Economics 1, 1 (2005):122.[Crossref] [Google Scholar], 2010 Searle, John. Making the Social World. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press, 2010. [Google Scholar]). The aim is a dynamic framework for the analysis of the institutional evolution of money, whereby institutional change comes from technology, and the state acts both as regulator of the institutional adjustment and guarantor of the stability and the efficiency of the monetary system. In that sense, the framework outlines the context and principles for the government regulation of financial innovation.  相似文献   

5.
Must banks match asset and liability maturities, as William Barnett and Walter E. Block (2009 Barnett, William and Walter E. Block. “Time Deposits, Dimensions and Fraud.Journal of Business Ethics 88, 4 (2009): 711716.[Crossref], [Web of Science ®] [Google Scholar], 2011 Barnett, William and Walter E. Block. “Rejoinder to Bagus and Howden on Borrowing Short and Lending Long.Journal of Business Ethics 100, 2 (2011): 229238.[Crossref], [Web of Science ®] [Google Scholar]), as well as Ivan Jankovic (2011) Jankovic, Ivan. “Economic Calculation, Maturity Mismatching and the Credit Cycle.New Perspectives on Political Economy 7, 1 (2011): 105124. [Google Scholar], surmise? While we agree with these authors that issuances of fiduciary media breed financial instability, we disagree that maturity transformation represents such a case. Maturity transformation — otherwise known as borrowing short-term and lending long-term — guided by several base legal principles, does not result in the issuance of fiduciary media. Most notable among these principles is that any credit issued must be funded by borrowing of a positive duration, i.e., not via a demand deposit. We demonstrate that two factors instigate larger degrees of maturity transformation than would otherwise be the case, breeding potential instability: a continual increase in the credit supply and the provision of a lender of last resort. We also show that the interest rate is a natural stabilizing brake on the over-issuance of longer-dated credit against short-term financing.  相似文献   

6.
This article examines the J-curve phenomenon for 16 European transition economies. While previous studies assume a linear relationship between the exchange rate and the trade balance, this paper allows for nonlinearity. Following Bahmani-Oskooee and Fariditavana (2015 Bahmani-Oskooee, M., and H. Fariditavana. 2015. “Nonlinear ARDL Approach, Asymmetric Effects and the J-curve.” Journal of Economic Studies 42 (3): 519530. doi:10.1108/JES-03-2015-0042.[Crossref], [Web of Science ®] [Google Scholar], 2016 Bahmani-Oskooee, M., and H. Fariditavana. 2016. “Nonlinear ARDL Approach and the J-curve Phenomenon.” Open Economies Review 27 (1): 5170. doi:10.1007/s11079-015-9369-5.[Crossref], [Web of Science ®] [Google Scholar]), the empirical method used is the nonlinear cointegrating autoregressive distributed lag (NARDL) model of Shin et al. (2013 Shin, Y., B. Yu, and M. J. Greenwood-Nimmo. 2013. “Modelling Asymmetric Cointegration and Dynamic Multipliers in a Nonlinear ARDL Framework.” In Festschrift in Honor of Peter Schmidt, edited by William C. Horrace and Robin C. Sickles. New York, NY: Springer Science and Business Media. [Google Scholar]) in which short-run and long-run nonlinearities are introduced via positive (appreciation) and negative (depreciation) partial sum decompositions of the real exchange rate. We argue that the lack of support for the J-curve phenomenon could be due to the linearity assumption. This issue is examined by utilizing the linear and the NARDL models. Using the linear autoregressive distributed lag (ARDL) model, we are unable to find support for the J-curve phenomenon in any case. However, when the NARDL model is used, we are able to find evidence for the J-curve in 12 out of the 16 countries. This suggests that allowing for nonlinearity in the adjustment process is important when studying the J-curve phenomenon.  相似文献   

7.
This article utilizes a simultaneous equations model to study the relationships among economic growth, banking and stock market development. In contrast to conventional instrumental variable approach, we implement the analysis via the methodology of identification through heteroscedasticity. Using Beck and Levine (2004 Beck, T. and Levine, R. (2004) Stock markets, banks and growth:panel evidence, Journal of Banking and Finance, 28, 42342.[Crossref], [Web of Science ®] [Google Scholar]) dataset, we find that each of the three variables interacts in important ways. While both are conducive to economic growth, banking development matters more for growth in low-income countries and stock market development is more favourable to growth in high-income or low-inflation ones. The data also reveal coexistence of a positive effect of banking development on stock market development and a negative effect of stock market development on banking development. Besides, the feedback effects of growth on both banking and stock market development are found.  相似文献   

8.
Sungju Chun 《Applied economics》2013,45(24):3512-3528
We study the finite sample properties of tests for structural changes in the trend function of a time series that do not require knowledge of the degree of persistence in the noise component. The tests of interest are the quasi-Feasible Generalized Least Squares (FGLS) procedure by Perron and Yabu (2009b Perron, P and Yabu, T. 2009b. Testing for shifts in trend with an integrated or stationary noise component. Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, 27: 36996. [Taylor &; Francis Online], [Web of Science ®] [Google Scholar]) and the weighted average of the regression t-statistics by Harvey et al. (2009 Harvey, DI, Leybourne, SJ and Taylor, AMR. 2009. Simple, robust, and powerful tests of the breaking trend hypothesis. Econometric Theory, 25: 9951029. [Crossref], [Web of Science ®] [Google Scholar]), both of which have the same limit distribution whether the noise component is stationary or has a unit-root. We analyse the finite sample size and power properties of these tests under a variety of Data-Generating Processes (DGPs). The results show that the Perron–Yabu test has greater power overall. With respect to the size, the Harvey–Leybourne–Taylor test exhibits larger size distortions unless a moving-average component is present. Using the Perron and Yabu procedure to test for structural changes in the trend function of long-run real exchange rates with respect to the US dollar indicates that for 17 out of 19 countries, the series have experienced a shift in trend since the late nineteenth century.  相似文献   

9.
The long-run equilibrium relationship among money, income, prices, and interest rates in Japan is investigated by the threshold cointegration test, which allows for asymmetric adjustment, introduced by Enders and Siklos (2001 Enders, W and Siklos, PL. 2001. Cointegration and threshold adjustment. Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, 19: 16676. [Taylor &; Francis Online], [Web of Science ®] [Google Scholar]). The threshold cointegration approach provides clear evidence of the cointegration relationship characterized by asymmetric adjustment. By allowing for asymmetric adjustment, results are obtained showing the stability of the money demand function, similar to Lucas (1988 Lucas, RW Jr. 1988. Money demand in the United States: a quantitative review. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 29: 13768.  [Google Scholar]), who pointed out that the money demand function is stable if unit income elasticity is imposed. In particular, the estimated results show that the adjustment process toward equilibrium is highly persistent above an appropriately estimated threshold, whereas the adjustment process toward equilibrium quickly converges below it. This finding indicates that deviations from equilibrium resulting from increases in money or decreases in income and prices are highly persistent.  相似文献   

10.
In their seminal work, Im et al. (1997 Im, KS, Pesaran, MH and Shin, Y. 1997. Testing for unit roots in heterogeneous panels. 1997. Working paper, Department of Applied Economics, University of Cambridge. Mimeographed [Google Scholar], 2003 Im, KS, Pesaran, MH and Shin, Y. 2003. Testing for unit roots in heterogeneous panels. Journal of Econometrics, 115: 5374. [Crossref], [Web of Science ®] [Google Scholar]) suggested that time series for several cross-sectional units could be used to increase the power of the Dickey--Fuller unit root test. They argued that when cross-sectional correlation is a problem that can be modelled by a time-specific factor, demeaning across the cross-sectional units can solve the problem. In this study, this proposition is proven valid, but it is also shown that previously supplied standardizing moments are inappropriate when the number of cross-sections are small, causing size to differ from the significance level. To correct this size distortion, the current paper supplies response surface parameters that can be used to obtain moments that are valid when a time-specific factor suffices for modelling cross-sectional correlation in the heterogeneous panel data unit root framework. The correct size of the panel data unit root test comes at the cost of a somewhat lower power against a stationary alternative.  相似文献   

11.
Jose L. Zofio 《Applied economics》2013,45(18):2371-2387
In two widely cited but unpublished working papers, Simar and Wilson (1998 Shephard, R. 1970. Theory of Cost and Production Functions, New Jersey: Princeton University Press.  [Google Scholar]) and Zofío and Lovell (1998 Wheelock, D and Wilson, PW. 1999. Technical progress, inefficiency, and productivity change in U.S. banking, 1984–1993. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 31: 21234. [Crossref], [Web of Science ®] [Google Scholar]) proposed an alternative decomposition of the Malmquist Productivity Index, which retained what seemed to be the strongholds of previous proposals with regard to the contribution of technological and efficiency change to productivity change. Namely, a technical change term with regard to the best practice variable returns to scale (VRS) technology, which is to be found in Ray and Desli (1997 Ray, S. Sept. 2001. “On an extended decomposition of the malmquist productivity index”. In Paper Presented at the Seventh European Workshop on Efficiency and Productivity, Sept., 2529. Oviedo: Universidad de Oviedo.  [Google Scholar]) and a scale efficiency change term that illustrates a firm's situation with regard to optimal scale (benchmark technology), Färe et al . (1994 Färe, R, Grosskopf, S and Norris, M. 1997. Productivity growth, technical progress, and efficiency change in industrialized countries: reply. American Economic Review, 87: 104043. [Web of Science ®] [Google Scholar]). Attaining this objective required the introduction of an additional term in the Malmquist Productivity Index decomposition, which would reflect the scale bias of technical change. It is our objective to provide economic rationale for this term within a theory of production context, the existing decompositions and recent articles that further elaborate on this issue. The ideas are illustrated using productivity trends in 17 OECD countries.  相似文献   

12.
We examine the export-led growth (ELG) hypothesis from a different perspective asking if the choice of data and/or methodology drives the results. We apply the Granger causality test modified by the corresponding error correction model using real export data from two common sources: the International Monetary Fund and the United Nations Commodity Trade Statistics. Additionally, to determine if the level of deflation could be a factor, we deflate the data at a disaggregated level and by a single export unit price index. Outcomes are compared to those obtained through the Granger causality procedure developed by Toda and Yamamoto (1995 Toda, H and Yamamoto, T. 1995. Statistical inference in vector autoregressions with possibly integrated process. Journal of Econometrics, 66: 22550. [Crossref], [Web of Science ®] [Google Scholar]) and Dolado and Lütkepohl (1996 Dolado, JJ and Lütkepohl, H. 1996. Making wald tests work for cointegrated VAR systems. Econometric Reviews, 15: 36986. [Taylor &; Francis Online] [Google Scholar]). We use sixteen Latin American countries to test our hypotheses. The analysis reveals inconsistencies in the results both by selection of data and methodology suggesting much of the debate regarding ELG, at least for Latin America, is fuelled by data and/or methodology choice, putting into question previous studies.  相似文献   

13.
This article uses household survey data to estimate the determinants of earnings in Indonesia, a country where nonsalaried work is widespread and earnings data are available for salaried employees only. We deal with the selection bias by estimating a Full-Information Maximum Likelihood (FIML) system of equations, where selection into the labour market is modelled in a multinomial setting. We find that some estimated parameters of the earnings equation differ from a binomial selection procedure by Heckman (1979 Heckman, J. 1979. Sample selection bias as a specification error. Econometrica, 47: 15361. [Crossref], [Web of Science ®] [Google Scholar]), in particular for those variables with the strongest impact on the selection into the different labour-market statuses. However, the estimated returns to education are unaffected, even when we deal with the endogeneity of educational attainment following Duflo (2001 Duflo, E. 2001. Schooling and labour market consequences of school construction in Indonesia: evidence from an unusual policy experiment. American Economic Review, 91: 795813. [Crossref], [Web of Science ®] [Google Scholar]). Overall, our findings show that the choice of the selection rule affects the estimates of the earnings determinants in the Indonesian labour market.  相似文献   

14.
This article focuses on the empirical approach proposed by Hall and Jones (1999 Hall, RE and Jones, CI(HJ99). 1999. Why do some countries produce so much more output per worker than others?. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114: 83116. [Crossref], [Web of Science ®] [Google Scholar]) to estimate the effect of what they call ‘social infrastructure’ on productivity across countries. We consider the issue of weak identification in their linear instrumental variables model. The evidence obtained from partially robust estimators, such as the k-class and jackknife estimators, is interpreted on the basis of Monte Carlo studies. Our findings suggest that using certain k-class estimators allows exclusive reliance on the linguistic variables to instrument for institutional quality despite their low correlation with the endogenous regressor in question.  相似文献   

15.
Abstract

We report the results from a series of trust games designed to distinguish racial discrimination from racial nepotism, played with a sample of high school students in Cape Town, South Africa. In contrast to the original work in this regard by Fershtman et al. (2005 Fershtman, C., Gneezy, U. and Verboven, F. 2005. “Discrimination and Nepotism: the efficiency of the anonymity rule,”. Journal of Legal Studies, 34: 371396. [Crossref], [Web of Science ®] [Google Scholar]), we find considerably greater heterogeneity in the way that proposers respond to the revealed racial identity of their partner, with nepotism being a dominant behavior. However, while some proposers exhibit a nepotistic bias in their offers that favors in-group members on average, others exhibit a nepotistic strategy that favors out-group members. A consequence of this nepotism is that both efficiency and equity are reduced on average.  相似文献   

16.
Assessing the scope for insurance in rural communities usually requires a structural model of household behaviour under risk. One of the few empirical applications of such models is the study by Rosenzweig and Wolpin (1993 Rosenzweig, MR and Wolpin, K. 1993. Credit market constraints, consumption smoothing, and the accumulation of durable production assets in low-income countries: investment in bullocks in India. Journal of Political Economy, 101: 22344. [Crossref], [Web of Science ®] [Google Scholar]) who conclude that Indian farmers in the ICRISAT villages would not benefit from the introduction of formal weather insurance. In this article we investigate how models such as theirs can be estimated from panel data on production and assets. We show that if assets can take only a limited number of values the coefficients of the model cannot be estimated with reasonable precision. We also show that this can affect the conclusion that insurance would not be welfare improving.  相似文献   

17.
P. S. Sephton 《Applied economics》2013,45(27):3439-3453
Lopez et al. (2005 Lopez, C, Murray, C and Papell, D. 2005. State of the art unit root tests and purchasing power parity. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 37: 3619. [Crossref], [Web of Science ®] [Google Scholar]) demonstrated that single-equation unit-root tests cannot provide conclusive evidence of whether real exchange rates are stationary because inference depends critically on the lag-lengths used to construct the test statistics, a result reinforced by a recent work by Sweeney (2006 Sweeney, D. 2006. Mean reversion in nominal G-10 exchange rates. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 41: 685708. [Crossref], [Web of Science ®] [Google Scholar]). The purpose of this article is to revisit the issue, first demonstrating the necessary conditions under which this approach of testing for Purchasing Power Parity (PPP) is appropriate.  相似文献   

18.
This paper contributes to our understanding of the determinants and dynamics of surplus-value using quarterly UK data, 1955–2010, and the Johansen (1988 Johansen, S. 1988. Statistical analysis of cointegrated vectors. Journal of Economic Dynamic and Control, 12: 23154. [Crossref], [Web of Science ®] [Google Scholar], 1991 Johansen, S. 1991. Estimation and hypothesis of cointegration vectors in Gaussian vector autoregressive models. Econometrica, 59: 155180. [Crossref], [Web of Science ®] [Google Scholar]) cointegration and vector error correction model (VECM). A model is introduced to define this Marxian concept, before we explain distribution, paying attention to three forces that are traditionally seen as drivers of power in this struggle: (i) working class militancy; (ii) the size of the ‘reserve army’ of the unemployed; and (iii) political party. Our results demonstrate the ongoing relevance of Marxian economics in providing an alternative, robust and significant explanation of distribution in the post-war UK economy.  相似文献   

19.
This article studies how adoption and usage behaviour of the Internet and online shopping, respectively influence the preference to use electronic commerce to purchase different types of products. We empirically model the preference for electronic commerce when consumers have to buy different types of products and thus face different types of risks (Cox and Rich, 1964 Cox, D and Rich, S. 1964. Perceived risk and consumer decision making-the case of telephone survey. Journal of Marketing Research, 1: 329. [Crossref], [Web of Science ®] [Google Scholar]). Unlike previous research, we find that consumers who have previously shopped online, display stronger preferences to buy products on the Internet irrespective of the perceived level of product-specific risks of online shopping. This article provides an interesting and novel insight into how both adoption and usage of electronic commerce impact on the attitude and risk perception of buying less predictable (more risky) products on the Internet.  相似文献   

20.
《Applied economics letters》2012,19(11):1125-1132
Employing disaggregated real exchange rates from nine European counties in 16 goods categories, we assess in this study the nonlinearity in the real exchange rates. Surprisingly, we find evidence for nonlinearity in only four (10) out of 143 series with the linearity test proposed by Harvey et al. (2008 Harvey, D. I., Leybourne, S. J. and Xiao, B. 2008. A powerful test for linearity when the order of integration is unknown. Studies in Nonlinear Dynamics and Econometrics, 12 Art 8[Web of Science ®] [Google Scholar]) at the 5% (10%) significance level. This result differs greatly from those of Juvenal and Taylor (2008 Juvenal, L. and Taylor, M. P. 2008. Threshold adjustment of deviations from the law of one price. Studies in Nonlinear Dynamics and Econometrics, 12 Art 8[Web of Science ®] [Google Scholar]), Imbs et al. (2003 Imbs, J., Mumtaz, H., Raven, M. O. and Rey, H. 2003. Nonlinearities and real exchange rate dynamics. Journal of the European Economic Association, 1: 63949. [Crossref] [Google Scholar]), Sarno et al. (2004 Sarno, L., Taylor, M. P. and Chowdhury, I. 2004. Nonlinear dynamics in deviations from the law of one price: a broad-based empirical study. Journal of International Money and Finance, 23: 125. [Crossref], [Web of Science ®] [Google Scholar]) and Berka (2009 Berka, M. 2009. “Non-linear adjustment in law of one price deviations and physical characteristic of good”. In Review of International Economics Vol. 17, 5173.  [Google Scholar]), who report ample evidence for nonlinearity for the same or similarly disaggregated real exchange rate datasets.  相似文献   

设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号