共查询到20条相似文献,搜索用时 15 毫秒
1.
Mangan D 《Medical economics》1999,76(23):38-40, 47-8, 51-2 passim
2.
Berent MD 《Medical economics》1995,72(24):44, 47-44, 48
3.
4.
《Journal of public economics》2005,89(2-3):327-350
Using data on the universe of students who graduated from US medical schools between 1996 and 1998, we examine whether the abilities and specialty preferences of a medical school class affect a student's academic achievement in medical school and his choice of specialty. We mitigate the selection problem by including school-specific fixed effects, and show that this method yields an upper bound on peer effects for our data. We estimate positive peer effects that disappear when school-specific fixed effects are added to control for the endogeneity of a peer group. We find no evidence that peer effects are stronger for blacks, that peer groups are formed along racial lines, or that students with relatively low ability benefit more from their peers than students with relatively high-ability. However, we do find some evidence that peer groups form along gender lines. 相似文献
5.
6.
Grandinetti DA 《Medical economics》2001,78(14):52-4, 63
The daily frustrations of medical practice take their toll on body and mind. These techniques can put you back in control. 相似文献
7.
8.
The recent euro area sovereign debt crisis has shown the importance of market reactions for the sustainability of debt in advanced economies. This paper calculates endogenous government debt limits given the markets assessment of the probability to default. The estimated primary balance reaction function to growing debt has the “fiscal fatigue” property (a loosening fiscal effort makes the primary balance insufficient to support rising debt) at high debt levels. The combination of this feature of the primary balance reaction function with the market interest rate reaction to growing debt determines the government debt limit beyond which debt cannot be rolled over. An application to OECD countries over the period 1985 – 2013 with a model-based risk-premium shows that current debt limits are high for most of the OECD thanks to particularly low risk-free interest rates. It also shows for some countries that current debt levels are not sustainable without a change in government behaviour. Most importantly, the framework illustrates the state contingent nature of debt limits and therefore the vulnerability of governments to a change in macroeconomic conditions and to market reactions. Last, computations with an estimated interest rate reaction to public debt illustrate that debt limits are lower in the euro area than in other countries because of a sharper market interest rate reaction to rising debt. 相似文献
9.
Projections indicate the US Federal debt held by the public may exceed 70–100% of GDP within 10 years. In many respects, the temptation to inflate away some of this debt burden is similar to that at the end of World War II. In 1946, the debt ratio was 108.6%. Inflation reduced this ratio by more than a third within a decade. Yet there are some important differences – shorter debt maturities today reduce the temptation to inflate, while the larger share of debt held by foreigners increases it. This paper lays out an analytical framework for determining the impact of a large nominal debt overhang on the temptation to inflate. It suggests that when economic growth is stalled, the US debt overhang may induce an increase in inflation of about 5% for several years that could significantly reduce the debt ratio. 相似文献
10.
Silvia Magri 《Empirical Economics》2007,33(3):401-426
This paper analyses Italian households’ participation to the debt market, separating the probability of demanding a loan from
the probability of being rationed by lenders; on the supply side of the market specific attention is paid to enforcement costs
of the loan contract when customers default. A new result is that the age of the household head acts essentially as a demand
factor, rather than a variable influencing the lender’s choice. Both current and future households’ income increase the demand
for loans and reduce credit rationing. Self-employed workers are more rationed by lenders. Credit constraints are also linked
to the area where the household lives, partly because of different enforcement costs. The final part of the paper analyses
the equilibrium quantity of the loan, for households who have a loan and are not constrained. The loan size is positively
linked to household net wealth and income profile. An important contribution of this paper is the finding that, not only the
participation to the debt market, but also the loan size is negatively affected by enforcement costs.
相似文献
11.
Understanding the factors that influence arrears is crucial if policy makers wish to alleviate the problems caused by debt. But conventional estimates of repayment behaviour impose implausible assumptions about lender behaviour. However, an upper and lower bound for the effect of the determinants of repayment behaviour can be estimated. Reasonable assumptions about the behaviour of economics agents narrow these bands. We use administrative data from a leading Italian lender to the household sector to demonstrate the methodology, and we show that conventional estimates under-estimate the true default probability. 相似文献
12.
13.
Grandinetti DA 《Medical economics》1996,73(11):229, 233-4, 239 passim
14.
15.
16.
17.
18.
19.
Slomski AJ 《Medical economics》1996,73(16):74-6, 81-2, 87-8 passim
20.