共查询到20条相似文献,搜索用时 0 毫秒
1.
Indrajit Ray 《Economic Theory》2001,17(1):223-231
Summary. This paper compares the sets of Nash, coalition- proof Nash and strong Nash equilibrium payoffs of normal form games which are closely related. We propose sufficient conditions for equivalent or closely related games to have identical sets of equilibrium payoffs. Received: April 23, 1999; revised version: November 23, 1999 相似文献
2.
Ko Nishihara 《Economic Theory》1999,13(2):483-494
Summary. Nishihara [3] showed that N-person prisoners' dilemma has a cooperative Nash equilibrium, if the players decide their actions sequentially in the order determined by Nature under a certain information structure, and if each player's payoffs satisfy a certain inequality. This paper examines the stability of this cooperative equilibrium against two matters: players' slight mistakes and deviations by coalitions. The main results are as follows: (i) if the inequality on each player's payoffs strictly holds, then the cooperative equilibrium is a strictly proper equilibrium; (ii) if N≤3, and if full cooperation is Pareto efficient in N-person prisoners' dilemma, then the cooperative equilibrium is a strong Nash equilibrium; (iii) the cooperative equilibrium is in general a coalition-proof Nash equilibrium. Received: June 23, 1997; revised version: December 2, 1997 相似文献
3.
Kin Chung Lo 《Economic Theory》1999,14(3):621-633
Summary. In a Nash equilibrium, players' rationality is mutual knowledge. However, both intuition and experimental evidence suggest that players do not know for sure the rationality of opponents. This paper proposes a new equilibrium concept, cautious equilibrium, that generalizes Nash equilibrium in terms of preferences in two person strategic games. In a cautious equilibrium, players do not necessarily know the rationality of opponents, but they view rationality as infinitely more likely than irrationality. For suitable models of preference, cautious equilibrium predicts that a player might take a “cautious” strategy that is not a best response in any Nash equilibrium. Received: January 28, 1998; revised version October 2, 1998 相似文献
4.
Yves Balasko 《Economic Theory》2003,21(1):1-18
Summary. In a two-period pure exchange economy with financial assets, a temporary financial equilibrium is an equilibrium of the current
spot and security markets given forecast functions of future prices and payoffs. The temporary equilibrium model can then
be interpreted as an Arrow-Debreu economy where preferences depend on prices. This identification implies, among other consequences,
the existence and the generic determinateness of the financial temporary equilibria associated with given forecast functions.
Received: December 29, 1999; revised version: December 20, 2001 相似文献
5.
Frank Riedel 《Economic Theory》2003,21(4):929-934
Summary. In infinite horizon economies only local equivalence of beliefs is needed to ensure the existence of an Arrow–Debreu equilibrium. In fact, agents can even disagree completely in the long run in the sense that asymptotically, their beliefs are singular. Received: November 3, 2000; revised version: February 13, 2002 相似文献
6.
Bernard Lebrun 《Economic Theory》2002,20(3):435-453
Summary. Despite the complexity of the first price auction in the general asymmetric case, analytical results have started to emerge
in the literature. Authors have also searched to gain insights by computing numerical estimates of the equilibria for some
probability distributions of the valuations. This paper proves that the Nash equilibrium of the first price auction depends
continuously, for the weak topology, on the valuation distributions and thus brings robustness to the numerical results as
well as some theoretical results. As an example of application, we disprove a conjecture of comparative statics.
Received: February 1, 1999; revised version: July 27, 2001 相似文献
7.
A note on asymmetric and mixed strategy equilibria in the search-theoretic model of fiat money 总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1
Randall Wright 《Economic Theory》1999,14(2):463-471
Summary. The simple search-theoretic model of fiat money has three symmetric Nash equilibria: all agents accept money with probability 1; all agents accept money with probability 0; and all agents accept money with probability y in (0,1). Here I construct an asymmetric pure strategy equilibrium, payoff-equivalent to the symmetric mixed strategy equilibrium, where a fraction N in (0,1) of agents always accept money and 1-N never accept money. Counter to what has been conjectured previously, I find N > y. I also introduce evolutionary dynamics, and show that the economy converges to monetary exchange iff the initial proportion of agents accepting money exceeds N. Received: September 10, 1997; revised version: April 24, 1998 相似文献
8.
Summary. We provide conditions for local stability and instability of an equilibrium point in certain systems of nonautonomous nonstochastic difference equations. In the systems under study the influence of time is present through a positive scalar “gain” parameter which converges in the limit to zero. These systems have recently been used to study the dynamics of adaptive learning in economic models, and we provide two economic illustrations of the formal results. Received: October 7, 1997; revised version: February 8, 1999 相似文献
9.
Jan Wenzelburger 《Economic Theory》2002,19(4):649-672
Summary. This paper develops an adaptive learning scheme for a standard version of the OLG model with pure exchange. Perfect forecasting
rules which generate perfect foresight orbits are approximated by cubic spline functions. These approximations are successively
constructed using historical data only. Trajectories generated by this scheme converge to perfect foresight orbits globally
for all initial conditions. This result holds for all parameterizations guaranteeing the existence of a monetary steady state
and hence is independent of consumers' savings behavior. It generalizes to all one-dimensional models of the Cobweb type.
Received: October 5, 2000; revised version: February 15, 2001 相似文献
10.
Summary. For a number of reasons a large class of general equilibrium models from the field of resource economics does not allow for an equilibrium analysis along the lines of the theory of infinite dimensional commodity spaces. The reasons concern the choice of the commodity space and the applicability of properness assumptions with respect to preferences and the technology. This paper illustrates the difficulties and shows for a prototype model how the problems can successfully be tackled by the use of a limit argument on equilibria in the truncated economies. Received: May 2, 1996; revised version: May 13, 1998 相似文献
11.
Contractual restrictions on insider trading: a welfare analysis 总被引:4,自引:0,他引:4
Antonio E. Bernardo 《Economic Theory》2001,18(1):7-35
Summary. This paper analyzes the welfare effects of permitting firms to negotiate contractually the right to allow corporate insiders to trade shares in the firm on private information. A computational framework is employed to (i) analyze formally the effects of insider trading on managerial investment choice, the informational efficiency of stock prices, and the welfare of all investor types; and (ii) examine the effectiveness of various compensation schemes (such as stock and insider trading rights) to mitigate conflicts of interest between managers and shareholders. I show that shareholders will typically choose not to grant insider trading rights to managers. This decision is socially optimal. Received: September 23, 2000; revised version: December 12, 2000 相似文献
12.
John Geanakoplos 《Economic Theory》2003,21(2-3):585-603
Summary. The existence of Nash and Walras equilibrium is proved via Brouwer's Fixed Point Theorem, without recourse to Kakutani's
Fixed Point Theorem for correspondences. The domain of the Walras fixed point map is confined to the price simplex, even when
there is production and weakly quasi-convex preferences. The key idea is to replace optimization with “satisficing improvement,”
i.e., to replace the Maximum Principle with the “Satisficing Principle.”
Received: July 9, 2001; revised version: February 25, 2002
RID="*"
ID="*" I wish to thank Ken Arrow, Don Brown, and Andreu Mas-Colell for helpful comments. I first thought about using Brouwer's
theorem without Kakutani's extension when I heard Herb Scarf's lectures on mathematical economics as an undergraduate in 1974,
and then again when I read Tim Kehoe's 1980 Ph.D dissertation under Herb Scarf, but I did not resolve my confusion until I
had to discuss Kehoe's presentation at the celebration for Herb Scarf's 65th birthday in September, 1995.
RID="*"
ID="*"Correspondence to: C. D. Aliprantis 相似文献
13.
Summary. Recent experiments on mixed-strategy play in experimental games reject the hypothesis that subjects play a mixed strategy
even when that strategy is the unique Nash equilibrium prediction. However, in a three-person matching-pennies game played
with perfect monitoring and complete payoff information, we cannot reject the hypothesis that subjects play the mixed-strategy
Nash equilibrium. Given this support for mixed-strategy play, we then consider two qualitatively different learning theories
(sophisticated Bayesian and naive Bayesian) which predict that the amount of information given to subjects will determine
whether they can learn to play the predicted mixed strategies. We reject the hypothesis that subjects play the symmetric mixed-strategy
Nash equilibrium when they do not have complete payoff information. This finding suggests that players did not use sophisticated
Bayesian learning to reach the mixed-strategy Nash equilibrium.
Received: August 9, 1996; revised version: October 21, 1998 相似文献
14.
Felix Kubler 《Economic Theory》2001,18(1):73-96
Summary. There are a wide variety of theoretical general equilibrium models with incomplete security markets. In this paper we give
a general recipe for using homotopy algorithm to compute equilibria in these models. In many models, taxes, transaction-costs
or other market frictions introduce the additional difficulty that equilibrium prices or choices (but not equilibrium allocations)
may be undetermined. In order to demonstrate how these difficulties can be dealt with, we develop a globally convergent algorithm
to compute equilibria in a model with cash-in-advance constraints, several goods and incomplete financial markets. Furthermore
we describe how to implement the algorithm using a publicly available suite of subroutines for homotopy-pathfollowing.
Received: October 1, 1999; revised version: December 16, 2000 相似文献
15.
Prabal Roy Chowdhury 《Economic Theory》2002,19(4):811-822
Summary. We consider a Bertrand duopoly model with increasing returns to scale where one of the firms have a cost advantage and prices
vary over a grid. We find that typically more than one equilibria exist. However, there are only two perfect equilibria. Moreover,
as the size of the grid becomes small, both these equilibria converge to the limit-pricing outcome.
Received: February 25, 2000; revised version: January 9, 2001 相似文献
16.
Moral hazard and general equilibrium in large economies 总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1
Marcos B. Lisboa 《Economic Theory》2001,18(3):555-575
Summary. The paper analyzes a two period general equilibrium model with individual risk, aggregate uncertainty and moral hazard. There is a large number of households, each facing two individual states of nature in the second period. These states differ solely in the household's vector of initial endowments, which is strictly larger in the first state (good state) than in the second state (bad state). In the first period each household chooses a non-observable action. Higher levels of action give higher probability of the good state of nature to occur, but lower levels of utility. Households' utilities are assumed to be separable in action and the aggregate uncertainty is independent of the individual risk. Insurance is supplied by a collection of firms who behave strategically and maximize expected profits taking into account that each household's optimal choice of action is a function of the offered contract. The paper provides sufficient conditions for the existence of equilibrium and shows that the appropriate versions of both welfare theorems hold. Received: December 7, 1998; revised version: October 25, 1999 相似文献
17.
Summary. We provide a “computable counterexample” to the Arrow-Debreu competitive equilibrium existence theorem [2]. In particular, we find an exchange economy in which all components are (Turing) computable, but in which no competitive equilibrium is computable. This result can be interpreted as an impossibility result in both computability-bounded rationality (cf. Binmore [5], Richter and Wong [35]) and computational economics (cf. Scarf [39]). To prove the theorem, we establish a “computable counterexample” to Brouwer's Fixed Point Theorem (similar to Orevkov [32]) and a computable analogue of a characterization of excess demand functions (cf. Mas-Colell [26], Geanakoplos [16], Wong [50]). Received: September 9, 1997; revised version: December 17, 1997 相似文献
18.
John Duggan 《Economic Theory》2003,21(1):117-131
Summary. I construct a general model of social planning problems, including mixed production economies and regulatory problems with
negative externalities as special cases, and I give simple mechanisms for Nash implementation under three increasingly general
sets of assumptions. I first construct a continuous mechanism to implement the (constrained) Lindahl allocations of an economy,
and I then extend this to arbitrary social choice rules based on prices. I end with a mechani
sm to implement any monotonic social choice rule, assuming only the existence of a private (not necessarily transferable)
good. In that general case, each agent simply reports an upper contour set, an outcome, and I need two agents to make binary
numerical announcements. I do not require the usual no-veto-power condition.
Received: February 19, 1998; revised version: January 30, 2002 相似文献
19.
Walter Trockel 《Economic Theory》2000,16(2):277-294
Summary. The present paper provides three different support results for the Nash bargaining solution of -person bargaining games. First, for any bargaining game there is defined a non-cooperative game in strategic form, whose unique Nash equilibrium induces a payoff vector that coincides with the Nash solution of the bargaining game. Next this game is modified in such a way that the unique Nash equilibrium that supports the Nash solution is even in dominant strategies. After that an -stage game in extensive form is presented whose unique subgame perfect equilibrium supports the Nash solution of the bargaining game. Finally, the support results are shown to induce implementation results in the sense of mechanism theory. Received: October 3, 1999; revised version: October 26, 1999 相似文献
20.
Elizabeth M. Caucutt 《Economic Theory》2001,17(1):25-51
Summary. In this paper, I develop an applied general equilibrium environment with peer group effects. The application I consider is
schooling. The framework used here is general equilibrium with clubs. I establish the existence of equilibrium for the economy
with a finite number of school types. This result is then extended to the case where the set of school types is a continuum.
The two welfare theorems are shown to hold for both economies. To compute the equilibrium, I construct a Negishi mapping from
the set of weights on individual type's utility to the set of transfers that support the corresponding Pareto allocations
as competitive equilibria with transfers. Because this mapping is a correspondence, a version of Scarf's algorithm is used
to find a competitive equilibrium.
Received: June 9, 1999; revised version: March 13, 2000 相似文献