共查询到20条相似文献,搜索用时 15 毫秒
1.
Entrepreneurship, structural change, and economic growth 总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1
Florian Noseleit 《Journal of Evolutionary Economics》2013,23(4):735-766
The ability to adjust to structural change is vital to economic development, and entries can be active participants in this process. While the importance of factor reallocations for growth is widely discussed, the role of entrepreneurs in managing these reallocations is currently not well understood. This paper analyzes the role of entry activity for adjustments of the sectoral structure and its relevance for regional economic development. The historical framework is the accelerated economic transformation that occurred in industrialized countries during the mid 1970s, resulting in an increasing need to adjust. Based on German data from 1975 to 2002, evidence is presented that sectoral reallocations are an important means for transforming entrepreneurial activity into growth. 相似文献
2.
Jochen Hartwig 《Structural Change and Economic Dynamics》2012,23(1):11-24
Against the backdrop of Baumol's model of ‘unbalanced growth’, a recent strand of literature has presented models that manage to reconcile structural change with Kaldor's ‘stylized fact’ of the relative constancy of per-capita real GDP growth. Another strand of literature goes beyond this, arguing that the expenditure shifts toward Baumol's ‘stagnant’ sector stimulate rather than dampen long-term economic growth because of the human capital-accumulating nature of major ‘stagnant’ services (like health care and education). This paper tests the relationship between structural change and economic growth empirically by means of a Granger-causality analysis of a panel of 18 OECD countries. 相似文献
3.
Gilles Lafforgue 《Resource and Energy Economics》2008,30(4):540-554
We develop a stochastic endogenous growth model involving a non-renewable resource, in which innovation arrivals are governed by a non-stationary Poisson process. Using a CRRA analytical example, we characterize the optimal trajectories of the model and analyze the effects of uncertainty in the sense of Rothschild and Stiglitz by computing a mean-preserving spread. We show that increased variability in the innovation process always implies a smaller optimal R&D effort, since this leads to a reduced marginal rate of return. Effects on the other variables of the model may also be unambiguously identified depending upon the relative risk aversion of agents, the social discount rate and the marginal arrival rate of innovations. Finally, we investigate the conditions under which, on average, the economy reaches a sustainable growth path. 相似文献
4.
Economic growth,structural change,and search unemployment 总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1
Martin Zagler 《Journal of Economics》2009,96(1):63-78
Economic growth is driven by structural change. Structural change does not come without a cost. The most evident social cost
of structural change is high and persistent unemployment. This paper develops a model with an endogenously expanding service
sector, where the constant flow of workers in and out of employment leads to structural unemployment. The main finding is
that the level of unemployment is different between the initial period and the long-run equilibrium growth path, and that
along the transition path, the level of unemployment will overshoot its equilibrium level, which can explain the long-run
pattern of unemployment in most industrialized countries.
相似文献
5.
Kishor Sharma 《Applied economics》2013,45(10):1253-1261
This paper presents an empirical analysis of the consequences of liberalization on industrial structure in Nepal, a least developed country with weak institutions and severe infrastructure bottlenecks. Results suggest some structural change in manufacturing output and trade orientation which appears to be due to a change in incentive structure, but no significant improvements were recorded in total factor productivity growth which is of central importance for a least developed country like Nepal. Export intensity rose significantly in the postliberalization period despite poor productivity performance of export-oriented industries while import intensity fell due mainly to improved competitiveness in import competing industries and a fall in imports for smuggling to India. 相似文献
6.
André Lorentz Tommaso Ciarli Maria Savona Marco Valente 《Journal of Evolutionary Economics》2016,26(1):219-246
The paper analyses the effect of the dynamics of consumption preferences on the dynamics of macro–economic growth. We endogenously derive micro–dynamics of consumption behavior as a result of the increase in the number of income classes. The different degrees of inertia in the adjustment of consumption levels to income changes affect firm selection and the dynamics of market structure, which is ultimately responsible for different regimes of macro–economic growth. We find, first, that higher heterogeneity in consumption preferences amplifies and accelerates market dynamics, leading to a swift shift from a Malthusian to a Kaldorian growth pattern. Second, consumption smoothing mainly affects the timing of such a take–off. Inertia in consumption delays the occurrence of a Kaldorian engine for growth. 相似文献
7.
《Structural Change and Economic Dynamics》2003,14(1):109-115
In a recent article, Fagerberg [Struct. Change Econ. Dyn. 11 (2000) 393] finds changes in the employment share of the electrical machinery industry to positively impact the manufacturing sector productivity growth. Fagerberg's approach has some methodological drawbacks, however. This note seeks to complement Fagerberg's analysis by estimating the impact of the employment share of technologically progressive industries using a more adequate methodology. Fagerberg's claim that the share of the ‘electronics’ industry positively affects manufacturing is confirmed. However, the size of the impact, and as a consequence the extent of spill-overs, is found to be much smaller than estimated by Fagerberg. 相似文献
8.
Frédéric Lordon 《Journal of Evolutionary Economics》1997,7(1):1-21
The slow and endogenous twist of economic macro-structure makes up an important evolutionary feature of capitalist economies,
and may be at the root of structural crisis. In this line, a Goodwinian growth model with increasing returns and profit-sharing
that tries to picture a simple scenario of the seventies crisis is considered. It is shown that the exhaustion of the Kaldor-Verdoorn
“productivity law” can entail, in a nonlinear framework, a “catastrophic” bifurcation from a “high” to a “low” growth path.
Slow/fast dynamical systems then allow one to formalize a multiple time-scales dynamics where the growth path is shaped by
the structural framework in which it takes place, but has also a long -un feedback. Structural change and crisis appear as
long term and endogenous outcomes. 相似文献
9.
Maura Sheehan 《International Review of Applied Economics》1997,11(1):155-158
10.
This paper provides a new definition of structural change and then categorizes such changes into two types. Transient structural change is related to the short-term adjustment of sectoral labor employment, while perpetual structural change concerns the long-run trends of labor reallocation among sectors. If we focus on supply-side reasons, we find that the one and only fundamental driving force of perpetual structural change is sector-biased technical change. We also investigate the structural parameters of the model that determine the direction of sector-biased technical change. 相似文献
11.
《Structural Change and Economic Dynamics》2000,11(1-2):45-65
A range of parameter changes in I(1) cointegrated time series are not reflected in econometric models thereof, in that many shifts are not easily detected by conventional tests. The breaks in question are changes that leave the unconditional expectations of the I(0) components unaltered. Thus, dynamics, adjustment speeds etc. may alter without detection. However, shifts in long-run means are generally noticeable. Using the VECM model class, the paper discusses such results, explains why they occur, and uses Monte Carlo experiments to illustrate the contrasting ease of detection of ‘deterministic’ and ‘stochastic’ shifts. 相似文献
12.
Portuguese Economic Journal - In this paper we study how the ongoing transition to newer technologies, what we refer to as dynamic structural change, in a doubly-differentiated R&D-based... 相似文献
13.
We study the effect of quadratic differentiation costs in the Hotelling model of endogenous product differentiation. The equilibrium
location choices are found to depend on the magnitude of the differentiation costs (relatively to the transportation costs
supported by consumers). When the differentiation costs are low, there is maximum differentiation. When they are high, there
is partial differentiation, with a degree of differentiation that decreases with the differentiation costs. In any case, the
socially optimal degree of differentiation is always lower than the equilibrium level. We also study the case of collusion
between firms. If firms can combine locations but not prices, they locate asymmetrically when differentiation costs are high
and choose maximum differentiation when they are low. When collusion extends to price setting, there is partial differentiation. 相似文献
14.
Tackseung Jun 《Economic Theory》2005,25(2):317-332
Summary. This paper extends the literature on the optimal switching rule between two investments by considering the case where switching between investments is costly. The model builds on the classic framework of the multi-armed Bandit problem by explicitly incorporating two key assumptions. First, switching investments is costly. Second, only the investment operated by the investor evolves as a random walk. The objective of the investor is to maximize the discounted sum of expected net profits over the infinite horizon. The main result is that when the volatility of profits from investments increases, so does the minimum profit gain needed for an investor to switch investments.JEL Classification Numbers:
C44, C61.I am indebted to Prajit K. Dutta for his guidance throughout this research. I am grateful for Presidents Summer 2000 Research Fellowship of Columbia University. I appreciate the comments from the anonymous referee. I also thank Lalith Munasinghe and Rajiv Sethi. I also thank Dr. Jong Myeon Kim for editing this version of the paper. 相似文献
15.
Michael L. Stern 《Economic Theory》2006,29(1):49-70
We adapt the classic one-sector optimal growth model to include an endogenous rate of time preference along the lines of Becker and Mulligan (1997). The resulting model is both time-consistent and analytically tractable. Capital sequences are shown to be globally monotone and stable under very general circumstances using lattice programming techniques and value orders. We analyze a series of examples that exhibit a variety of behaviors, including closed-form solutions, unique steady-states, multiple steady-states, and conditionally sustained growth. The endogenous rate of discount preserves monotonicity and stability while allowing for the possibility of non-global convergence.I would like to thank Robert Becker, Leonard Mirman, Michael Kaganovich, Itzhak Zilcha, and an anonymous referee for helpful comments and discussions. 相似文献
16.
17.
A general equilibrium model of structural change and economic growth,with application to south Korea
《Journal of development economics》1986,23(1):67-88
This paper presents a computable general equilibrium model for South Korea. It is a dynamic input-output model solved by assuming equal sectoral growth rates. Its solution gives output and price relatives which measure the structural ‘distance’ of the economy from the ‘turnpike’. Comparisons of these model solutions with actual output proportions and relative prices provide insights into the South Korean industrialization process. However, the model's strict assumptions limit its applicability and provide problems of interpretation, especially in open economies. 相似文献
18.
19.
We consider broad patterns of structural change: (i) sectoral reallocations, (ii) rich movements of productive activities between home and market, and (iii) an increase in establishment size, especially in manufacturing. We extend these facts and develop a unified model explaining them. The crucial distinction across manufacturing, services and home production is the scale of the productive unit. In manufacturing, scale technologies lead to industrialization and marketization. In services, they lead to marketization and later demarketization of services. A later increase in the scale of services could yield a decline in industry and a rise in services, consistent with the data. 相似文献
20.
We present a model of structural change in the farming sector in which natural and economic crises decrease farmers’ work satisfaction, farm profitability, and the decision to stay in farming. Using data from the Australian Regional Well-being survey, activity choice modeling, and a structural equation approach, we test the hypothesis that these crises-induced effects then cause structural change in Australian agriculture. We find that external shocks, such as drought or economic downturn, negatively affect farmers’ welfare, which in turn causes structural change through revised activity choices. Our empirical findings also indicate that specific adjustment strategies such as buying additional water titles or reducing input use are insufficient to mitigate adverse crises effects. 相似文献