共查询到20条相似文献,搜索用时 15 毫秒
1.
We develop a new approach for pricing European-style contingent claims written on the time T spot price of an underlying asset whose volatility is stochastic. Like most of the stochastic volatility literature, we assume
continuous dynamics for the price of the underlying asset. In contrast to most of the stochastic volatility literature, we
do not directly model the dynamics of the instantaneous volatility. Instead, taking advantage of the recent rise of the variance
swap market, we directly assume continuous dynamics for the time T variance swap rate. The initial value of this variance swap rate can either be directly observed, or inferred from option
prices. We make no assumption concerning the real world drift of this process. We assume that the ratio of the volatility
of the variance swap rate to the instantaneous volatility of the underlying asset just depends on the variance swap rate and
on the variance swap maturity. Since this ratio is assumed to be independent of calendar time, we term this key assumption
the stationary volatility ratio hypothesis (SVRH). The instantaneous volatility of the futures follows an unspecified stochastic
process, so both the underlying futures price and the variance swap rate have unspecified stochastic volatility. Despite this,
we show that the payoff to a path-independent contingent claim can be perfectly replicated by dynamic trading in futures contracts
and variance swaps of the same maturity. As a result, the contingent claim is uniquely valued relative to its underlying’s
futures price and the assumed observable variance swap rate. In contrast to standard models of stochastic volatility, our
approach does not require specifying the market price of volatility risk or observing the initial level of instantaneous volatility.
As a consequence of our SVRH, the partial differential equation (PDE) governing the arbitrage-free value of the contingent
claim just depends on two state variables rather than the usual three. We then focus on the consistency of our SVRH with the
standard assumption that the risk-neutral process for the instantaneous variance is a diffusion whose coefficients are independent
of the variance swap maturity. We show that the combination of this maturity independent diffusion hypothesis (MIDH) and our
SVRH implies a very special form of the risk-neutral diffusion process for the instantaneous variance. Fortunately, this process
is tractable, well-behaved, and enjoys empirical support. Finally, we show that our model can also be used to robustly price
and hedge volatility derivatives. 相似文献
2.
Bertram Düring 《Review of Derivatives Research》2009,12(2):141-167
Based on a general specification of the asset specific pricing kernel, we develop a pricing model using an information process
with stochastic volatility. We derive analytical asset and option pricing formulas. The asset prices in this rational expectations
model exhibit crash-like, strong downward movements. The resulting option pricing formula is consistent with the strong negative
skewness and high levels of kurtosis observed in empirical studies. Furthermore, we determine credit spreads in a simple structural
model.
相似文献
3.
Efficient valuation of exchange options with random volatilities while challenging at analytical level, has strong practical implications: in this paper we present a new approach to the problem which allows for extensions of previous known results. We undertake a route based on a multi-asset generalization of a methodology developed in Antonelli and Scarlatti (Finan Stoch 13:269–303, 2009) to handle simple European one-asset derivatives with volatility paths described by Ito’s diffusive equations. Our method seems to adapt rather smoothly to the evaluation of Exchange options involving correlations among all the financial quantities that specify the model and it is based on expanding and approximating the theoretical evaluation formula with respect to correlation parameters. It applies to a whole range of models and does not require any particular distributional property. In order to test the quality of our approximation numerical simulations are provided in the last part of the paper. 相似文献
4.
Jack C. Lee Cheng F. Lee K. C. John Wei 《Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting》1991,1(4):435-448
This research extends the binomial option-pricing model of Cox, Ross, and Rubinstein (1979) and Rendleman and Barter (1979)
to the case where the up and down percentage changes of stock prices are stochastic. Assuming stochastic parameters in the
discrete-time binomial option pricing is analogous to assuming stochastic volatility in the continuous-time option pricing.
By assuming that the up and down parameters are independent random variables following beta distributions, we are able to
derive a closed-form solution to this stochastic discrete-time option pricing. We also derive an upper and a lower bounds
of the option price. 相似文献
5.
唐明琴 《广东金融学院学报》2007,22(5):36-40
近年来随着计算机技术的飞速发展,美式期权的Monte Carlo模拟法定价取得了实质性的突破。本文分析介绍了美式期权的Monte Carlo模拟法定价理论及在此基础上推导出的线性回归MonteCarlo模拟法定价公式及其在实际的应用。 相似文献
6.
The number of tailor-made hybrid structured products has risen more prominently to fit each investor’s preferences and requirements as they become more diversified. The structured products entail synthetic derivatives such as combinations of bonds and/or stocks conditional on how they are backed up by underlying securities, stochastic volatility, stochastic interest rates or exchanges rates. The complexity of these multi-asset structures yields lots of difficulties of pricing the products. Because of the complexity, Monte-Carlo simulation is a possible choice to price them but it may not produce stable Greeks leading to a trouble in hedging against risks. In this light, it is desirable to use partial differential equations with relevant analytic and numerical techniques. Even if the partial differential equation method would generate stable security prices and Greeks for single asset options, however, it may result in the curse of dimensionality when pricing multi-asset derivatives. In this study, we make the best use of multi-scale nature of stochastic volatility to lift the curse of dimensionality for up to three asset cases. Also, we present a transformation formula by which the pricing group parameters required for the multi-asset options in illiquid market can be calculated from the underlying market parameters. 相似文献
7.
Oleksandr Zhylyevskyy 《Review of Derivatives Research》2010,13(1):1-24
This paper develops a non-finite-difference-based method of American option pricing under stochastic volatility by extending the Geske-Johnson compound option scheme. The characteristic function of the underlying state vector is inverted to obtain the vector’s density using a kernel-smoothed fast Fourier transform technique. The method produces option values that are closely in line with the values obtained by finite-difference schemes. It also performs well in an empirical application with traded S&P 100 index options. The method is especially well suited to price a set of options with different strikes on the same underlying asset, which is a task often encountered by practitioners. 相似文献
8.
This paper develops a simple model for pricing interest rate options when the volatility structure of forward rates is humped. Analytical solutions are developed for European claims and efficient algorithms exist for pricing American options. The interest rate claims are priced in the Heath-Jarrow-Morton paradigm, and hence incorporate full information on the term structure. The structure of volatilities is captured without using time varying parameters. As a result, the volatility structure is stationary. It is not possible to have all the above properties hold in a Heath Jarrow Morton model with a single state variable. It is shown that the full dynamics of the term structure is captured by a three state Markovian system. Caplet data is used to establish that the volatility hump is an important feature to capture. This revised version was published online in June 2006 with corrections to the Cover Date. 相似文献
9.
Bing-Huei Lin Mao-Wei Hung Jr-Yan Wang Ping-Da Wu 《Review of Derivatives Research》2013,16(3):295-329
This study extends the GARCH pricing tree in Ritchken and Trevor (J Financ 54:366–402, 1999) by incorporating an additional jump process to develop a lattice model to value options. The GARCH-jump model can capture the behavior of asset prices more appropriately given its consistency with abundant empirical findings that discontinuities in the sample path of financial asset prices still being found even allowing for autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity. With our lattice model, it shows that both the GARCH and jump effects in the GARCH-jump model are negative for near-the-money options, while positive for in-the-money and out-of-the-money options. In addition, even when the GARCH model is considered, the jump process impedes the early exercise and thus reduces the percentage of the early exercise premium of American options, particularly for shorter-term horizons. Moreover, the interaction between the GARCH and jump processes can raise the percentage proportions of the early exercise premiums for shorter-term horizons, whereas this effect weakens when the time to maturity increases. 相似文献
10.
Massimo Costabile Arturo Leccadito Ivar Massabó Emilio Russo 《Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting》2014,42(4):667-690
We present a binomial approach for pricing contingent claims when the parameters governing the underlying asset process follow a regime-switching model. In each regime, the asset dynamics is discretized by a Cox–Ross–Rubinstein lattice derived by a simple transformation of the parameters characterizing the highest volatility tree, which allows a simultaneous representation of the asset value in all the regimes. Derivative prices are computed by forming expectations of their payoffs over the lattice branches. Quadratic interpolation is invoked in case of regime changes, and the switching among regimes is captured through a transition probability matrix. An econometric analysis is provided to pick reasonable volatility values for option pricing, for which we show some comparisons with the existing models to assess the goodness of the proposed approach. 相似文献
11.
Discrete time option pricing with flexible volatility estimation 总被引:3,自引:0,他引:3
12.
Review of Derivatives Research - We propose a novel model-free approach to extract a joint multivariate distribution, which is consistent with options written on individual stocks as well as on... 相似文献
13.
Shibor自2007年发布以来,已成为人民币利率市场的一个重要定价基准,对金融衍生品、债券的定价起着十分重要的作用,由于人民币利率衍生品市场尚处于发展的初期,与美元Libor利率期权等较为成熟市场相比,目前Shibor利率期权缺少成熟的市场报价。本文通过风险中性的定价方程反解参数的方法,利用Shibor利率掉期曲线对Shibor利率上下限期权的隐含波动率进行计算,从而探讨对Shibor利率期权的定价。 相似文献
14.
Jeroen V.K. Rombouts 《Journal of Banking & Finance》2011,35(9):2267-2281
In this paper we consider option pricing using multivariate models for asset returns. Specifically, we demonstrate the existence of an equivalent martingale measure, we characterize the risk neutral dynamics, and we provide a feasible way for pricing options in this framework. Our application confirms the importance of allowing for dynamic correlation, and it shows that accommodating correlation risk and modeling non-Gaussian features with multivariate mixtures of normals substantially changes the estimated option prices. 相似文献
15.
DAVID EDELMAN 《Abacus》1995,31(1):113-119
The Lognormal price model is generalized to the class of Log-Stable Processes, a family which possesses self-similarity properties usually only associated with the Lognormal, but which, more generally, can model negatively skewed distributions of return. This generalization appears to explain several discrepancies between the Black-Scholes Model and observed market phenomena, such as the variation of implied volatility of option price with exercise price and term to expiry, and the nonzero probability of bankruptcy or ‘crash’. It will be argued that the class of maximally negatively skewed Stable distributions (a class which, paradoxically, contains the normal) may be utilized to produce models which imply these phenomena naturally. 相似文献
16.
This study integrates CBOE VIX Term Structure and VIX futures to simplify VIX option pricing in multifactor models. Exponential and hump volatility functions with one- to three-factor models of the VIX evolution are used to examine their pricing for VIX options across strikes and maturities. The results show that using exponential volatility functions presents an effective choice as pricing models for VIX calls, whereas hump volatility functions provide efficient out-of-sample valuation for most VIX puts, in particular with deep in-the-money and deep out-of-the-money. Pricing errors for calls can be further reduced with a two-factor model. 相似文献
17.
Option pricing models based on an underlying lognormal distribution typically exhibit volatility smiles or smirks where the implied volatility varies by strike price. To adequately model the underlying distribution, a less restrictive model is needed. A relaxed binomial model is developed here that can account for the skewness of the underlying distribution and a relaxed trinomial model is developed that can account for the skewness and kurtosis of the underlying distribution. The new model incorporates the usual binomial and trinomial tree models as restricted special cases. Unlike previous flexible tree models, the size and probability of jumps are held constant at each node so only minor modifications in existing code for lattice models are needed to implement the new approach. Also, the new approach allows calculating implied skewness and implied kurtosis. Numerical results show that the relaxed binomial and trinomial tree models developed in this study are at least as accurate as tree models based on lognormality when the true underlying distribution is lognormal and substantially more accurate when the underlying distribution is not lognormal. 相似文献
18.
Jeff Fleming 《Journal of Empirical Finance》1998,5(4):317-345
This study examines the performance of the S&P 100 implied volatility as a forecast of future stock market volatility. The results indicate that the implied volatility is an upward biased forecast, but also that it contains relevant information regarding future volatility. The implied volatility dominates the historical volatility rate in terms of ex ante forecasting power, and its forecast error is orthogonal to parameters frequently linked to conditional volatility, including those employed in various ARCH specifications. These findings suggest that a linear model which corrects for the implied volatility's bias can provide a useful market-based estimator of conditional volatility. 相似文献
19.
Alfredo Ibáñez 《Review of Derivatives Research》2008,11(3):205-244
Existing evidence indicates that average returns of purchased market-hedge S&P 500 index calls, puts, and straddles are non-zero
but large and negative, which implies that options are expensive. This result is intuitively explained by means of volatility
risk and a negative volatility risk premium, but there is a recent surge of empirical and analytical studies which also attempt
to find the sources of this premium. An important question in the line of a priced volatility explanation is if a standard
stochastic volatility model can also explain the cross-sectional findings of these empirical studies. The answer is fairly
positive. The volatility elasticity of calls and puts is several times the level of market volatility, depending on moneyness
and maturity, and implies a rich cross-section of negative average option returns—even if volatility risk is not priced heavily,
albeit negative. We introduce and calibrate a new measure of option overprice to explain these results. This measure is robust
to jump risk if jumps are not priced.
相似文献
20.
We investigate and compare two dual formulations of the American option pricing problem based on two decompositions of supermartingales:
the additive dual of Haugh and Kogan (Oper. Res. 52:258–270, 2004) and Rogers (Math. Finance 12:271–286, 2002) and the multiplicative
dual of Jamshidian (Minimax optimality of Bermudan and American claims and their Monte- Carlo upper bound approximation. NIB
Capital, The Hague, 2003). Both provide upper bounds on American option prices; we show how to improve these bounds iteratively
and use this to show that any multiplicative dual can be improved by an additive dual and vice versa. This iterative improvement
converges to the optimal value function. We also compare bias and variance under the two dual formulations as the time horizon
grows; either method may have smaller bias, but the variance of the multiplicative method typically grows much faster than
that of the additive method. We show that in the case of a discrete state space, the additive dual coincides with the dual
of the optimal stopping problem in the sense of linear programming duality and the multiplicative method arises through a
nonlinear duality.
相似文献