共查询到20条相似文献,搜索用时 0 毫秒
1.
Maiting Zhuang 《Economics of Transition》2019,27(1):67-97
Do political connections affect investment in human capital? This paper studies the higher education decisions of politically connected and unconnected students during China's economic transition. Using the sequential introduction of reforms, I show that economic liberalization increased tertiary educational attainment, as well as sorting of students into different degree types depending on family background. Students whose parents were members of the Chinese Communist Party selected into relatively less prestigious vocational colleges with lower admissions standards. In contrast, politically unconnected individuals responded to the higher skill premium following the reforms by studying harder to obtain more demanding and sought‐after university degrees. 相似文献
2.
Past studies predict that trade liberalization agreements (and NAFTA in particular) harm the environment. These studies have focused on adjustments in production and have assumed that environmental policy is exogenously given. We show why trade liberalization and improved environmental quality are mutually compatible — when environmental policy is recognized as politically endogenous. We also present empirical evidence to support the basic assumptions underlying the consistency of more liberal trade policy and an improved environment. 相似文献
3.
Roger B. Myerson 《Theoretical Economics》2010,5(1):73-91
We consider a simple political‐economic model where capitalist investment is constrained by the government's temptation to expropriate. Political liberalization can relax this constraint, increasing the government's revenue, but also increasing the ruler's political risks. We analyze the ruler's optimal liberalization, where our measure of political liberalization is the probability of the ruler being replaced if he tried to expropriate private investments. Poorer endowments can support reputational equilibria with more investment, even without liberalization, so we find a resources curse, where larger resource endowments can decrease investment and reduce the ruler's revenue. The ruler's incentive to liberalize can be greatest with intermediate resource endowments. Strong liberalization becomes optimal in cases where capital investment yields approximately constant returns to scale. Adding independent revenue decreases optimal liberalization and investment. Mobility of productive factors that complement capital can increase incentives to liberalize, but equilibrium prices may adjust so that liberal and authoritarian regimes coexist. 相似文献
4.
5.
《Journal of Comparative Economics》2022,50(1):196-220
We study how local leaders matter for economic growth by examining the impacts of exogenous transfers of leaders across China’s provinces on land transactions in the primary market. We find that new provincial leaders attract investment in industrial land from the provinces of their previous positions. The leaders’ impacts are greater when their freedom to deploy their business connections in the land market is greater. More importantly, we find evidence of positive impacts of land transactions on economic growth, which should bode well for the careers of the local leaders, albeit there is some evidence of rent seeking among officials especially when they are too old for further promotion. 相似文献
6.
Edward L. Glaeser Giacomo A. M. Ponzetto Andrei Shleifer 《Journal of Economic Growth》2007,12(2):77-99
Across countries, education and democracy are highly correlated. We motivate empirically and then model a causal mechanism
explaining this correlation. In our model, schooling teaches people to interact with others and raises the benefits of civic
participation, including voting and organizing. In the battle between democracy and dictatorship, democracy has a wide potential
base of support but offers weak incentives to its defenders. Dictatorship provides stronger incentives to a narrower base.
As education raises the benefits of civic engagement, it raises participation in support of a broad-based regime (democracy)
relative to that in support of a narrow-based regime (dictatorship). This increases the likelihood of successful democratic
revolutions against dictatorships, and reduces that of successful anti-democratic coups. 相似文献
7.
Several empirical studies have established the relationship between economic freedom, civil liberties and political rights, and economic growth. Nevertheless, few studies analyze the directions of causality. This paper studies the causality relations between the institutional dimensions mentioned above and economic growth, as well as the interrelations between them, using the Granger methodology with panel data for 187 countries and five-yearly observations for the period 1976–2000. In addition, the relations between these freedoms and investment in physical and human capital are examined, to be able to isolate the direct and indirect effects on growth. The authors acknowledge the suggestions made by the editor and the reviewers, which have improved this work with respect to its initial version. 相似文献
8.
论政府供给偏好的短期决定:政治均衡与经济效率 总被引:6,自引:0,他引:6
本文以财政支出为主体,研究了我国政府供给偏好(规模与结构)短期决定问题。政治均衡而非经济市场均衡是理解这一问题的关键。在“有管理的竞争性政治市场”和政府追求政治支持最大化等假定下,我们考察了政治均衡决定政府供给偏好的过程及其效率属性,以及“政治价格”在两级“政治市场”上的形成机制。结论表明:政治均衡决定资源配置固有的低效率属性,因政府供给范围的“越位”和“缺位”而加剧。当前改革的重点应是推动经济市场化转轨的完成和公共财政的转型,而非完全的民主化。权威因素对“政治价格”的管理在利益分化严重的当前形势下具有建设性作用。推动渐进民主化,完善权力对等的“二级政治市场”则是长远之策。 相似文献
9.
Ling Shen 《Economic Theory》2007,31(2):343-366
Dictatorship is the predominant political system in many developing countries. However, different dictators act quite differently:
a good dictator implements growth-enhancing economic policies, e.g., investment in public education and infrastructure, whereas
a bad dictator taxes her citizens for her own consumption. The present paper provides a theoretical model by deriving underlying
determinants of dictatorial behavior. We assume that the engine of economic growth is private investment. It can increase
the productivity of individuals who invest, as well as the aggregate technological level. A good dictator encourages this
investment in order to tax more. However, the cost of this encouragement is that the ensuing higher growth rate will induce
earlier democratization. In this paper we will illustrate the risk of choosing a growth-enhancing policy, while leading to
additional tax revenues in the short-run will also increase the likelihood of a revolution resulting in the eventual overthrow
of the dictator. Furthermore, we will find that the higher the return from private investments the less likely the dictator
will be a good one. Contrary to McGuire and Olson (J Econ Lit 34:72–96, 1996) we find that a long life-time does not always
induce positive incentives among dictators.
I wish to thank Monika Merz, who carefully read the earlier version of this paper and provided many valuable suggestions.
I also would like to thank the editor, the anonymous referee, Uwe Sunde, Philipp Kircher and participants at the 4th international
annual conference of JEPA for helpful comments. I am grateful to Stephan Heim for his assistance. All possible errors are,
of course, mine. 相似文献
10.
In 1989, Argentina entered a process of sweeping transformation of its economic institutions which provided for the (temporary) recovery of economic growth and the taming of inflation. The Argentine experience with market-oriented reforms has been regarded by the literature as a salient case of radical and 'unconstrained' reform. Yet, a closer scrutiny portrays that the building and maintenance of a pro-\"reform coalition determined the pace, depth and characteristics of the 'new economic institutions'. The idiosyncrasies of Argentina's political institutions, in turn, conditioned this coalition-building strategy. The same idiosyncrasies were at play in the 2001/2002 collapse of the convertibility regime and ensuing social and political chaos. 相似文献
11.
Gernot Sieg 《Scottish journal of political economy》2006,53(2):242-252
According to political business cycle theory, separate opportunistic and partisan approaches exist. It is obvious, as seen from theoretical and empirical points of view, that politicians aim for both opportunistic as well as partisan goals. This paper presents a model of a pre‐election political business cycle that manifests an indication of competence and a post‐election political business cycle that occurs because of the uncertainty of an election's winner monetary policy. In the pre‐election period competent governments expand the economy. The post‐election cycle depends on whether a leftist or a conservative government is in power in the pre‐election period, and if they are re‐elected or not. 相似文献
12.
The impact of women's rights on a country's competitiveness in the global economy is a source of contention. While educational opportunities for women, as well as political empowerment, are linked to a variety of positive outcomes, the impact of economic rights is mixed. Toward better understanding these issues, we focus on the role of women's rights in attracting foreign direct investment (FDI). Though foreign capital plays a key role in the development strategies of many countries, and many of the growth areas in FDI rely heavily on women's labor, extant literature on the determinants of FDI largely ignores gender. To gain insight into these issues, we examine the impact of women's political, economic, and educational rights across four different types of US FDI into the developing world. We find a mixed relationship between women's rights and FDI that varies across industrial sectors. 相似文献
13.
经济转轨、集体腐败与政治改革--基于中国转轨经验的经济学分析 总被引:6,自引:0,他引:6
腐败是经济转轨国家中普遍存在的现象,中国当前的腐败问题呈现集体腐败的特征.文章主要是运用博弈理论对集体腐败行为进行解释.文章证明了在中国这样的经济转轨国家,由于缺乏一个独立的监督机构,一般都是上级官员作为其下级官员的监督者,他们非常容易合谋,形成集体腐败.随后文章对中国集体腐败问题做了实证分析,并且提出了相应的政治改革措施. 相似文献
14.
In this article, we study the impact of trade liberalization, including reductions in both tariff and nontariff trade barriers, on environmental goods (EGs) exports. Using bilateral trade data from 20 Asia-Pacific Economic Cooperation members, we find that tariff reduction in an exporting country has a larger positive impact on its exports of EGs than tariff reduction in an importing country. Our results also show that a lower nontariff barrier in an importing country increases its imports of EGs. A considerable amount of heterogeneity also exists in subsample results based on countries’ income levels. 相似文献
15.
We examine the effect of political ‘institutions’ on economic growth volatility, using data from more than 100 countries over the period 1960 to 2005, taking into account various control variables as suggested in previous studies. Our indicator of volatility is the relative standard deviation of the growth rate of GDP per capita. The results of a dynamic panel model indicate that democracy reduces economic volatility. We also find that some dimensions of political instability and policy uncertainty increase economic volatility. 相似文献
16.
17.
Growth and human capital: good data,good results 总被引:7,自引:0,他引:7
We present a new data set for years of schooling across countries for the 1960–2000 period. The series are constructed from
the OECD database on educational attainment and from surveys published by UNESCO. Two features that improve the quality of
our data with respect to other series, particularly for series in first-differences, are the use of surveys based on uniform
classification systems of education over time, and an intensified use of information by age groups. As a result of the improvement
in quality, these new series can be used as a direct substitute for Barro and Lee’s (2001; Oxford Economic Papers, 3, 541–563)
data in empirical research. In standard cross-country growth regressions we find that our series yield significant coefficients
for schooling. In panel data estimates our series are also significant even when the regressions account for the accumulation
of physical capital. Moreover, the estimated macro return is consistent with those reported in labour studies. These results
differ from the typical findings of the earlier literature and are a consequence of the reduction in measurement error in
the series.
相似文献
18.
Jason Brennan 《Constitutional Political Economy》2007,18(4):287-299
Rawls’ theory of justice is paradoxical, for it requires a society to aim directly to maximize the basic goods received by
the least advantaged even if directly aiming is self-defeating. Rawls’ reasons for rejecting capitalist systems commit him
to holding that a society must not merely maximize the goods received by the least advantaged, but must do so via specific
institutions. By Rawls’ own premises, in the long run directly aiming to satisfy the difference principle is contrary to the
interests of the poor, though it is meant to aid them.
相似文献
Jason BrennanEmail: |
19.
This paper investigates the empirical relationship between financial liberalization and economic growth in East Asian region. The empirical literature suggests that there is a mixed link between financial liberalization and growth in emerging countries. Panel data techniques using LS, TSLS, and GMM are employed to shed some light on the empirical debate, we examine this issue in 6 major emerging East Asian countries over the period 1980–2002. The main result is that financial liberalization's growth effect depends on the nature as well as the intensity of financial sectors liberalization. Full liberalization of the financial sector has been associated with slower growth outcomes while more moderate partial liberalization is associated with more positive outcomes. 相似文献
20.
Peter Söderbaum 《Journal of Bioeconomics》2007,9(3):205-225
Synopsis Radical alternatives, in terms of our ideas about science in society, about economics, ideology and institutional arrangements,
should be included among possibilities considered within the scope of a pluralistic philosophy. While all these aspects of
our mental maps are interrelated and important, economics plays a key role in attempts to get closer to a sustainable society.
Mainstream neoclassical economics is not enough. The tendency to exclusively rely on this particular theory is considered
part of the problems faced. A ‘sustainability economics’ more in line with dominant ideas of democracy is proposed, emphasizing
the ethical, ideological and political elements. Reference is made to institutional theory but the principles and concepts
suggested are in many ways similar to other kinds of heterodox economics and developments in other social sciences. Neoclassical
economics is used as a point of reference in pointing to alternative ideas about human beings, organizations, markets, decision-
making, efficiency, rationality, progress in society and institutional change processes. Predilection for such an alternative
conceptual framework (or for neoclassical economics) is not exclusively a scientific choice but as much a matter of political
and ideological preferences. One paradigm may be dominant at a time, but because of the ideological specificity of each paradigm,
competing theoretical perspectives should be accepted and even encouraged in a democratic society.
相似文献