共查询到20条相似文献,搜索用时 15 毫秒
1.
Oleksandr Zhylyevskyy 《Review of Derivatives Research》2010,13(1):1-24
This paper develops a non-finite-difference-based method of American option pricing under stochastic volatility by extending the Geske-Johnson compound option scheme. The characteristic function of the underlying state vector is inverted to obtain the vector’s density using a kernel-smoothed fast Fourier transform technique. The method produces option values that are closely in line with the values obtained by finite-difference schemes. It also performs well in an empirical application with traded S&P 100 index options. The method is especially well suited to price a set of options with different strikes on the same underlying asset, which is a task often encountered by practitioners. 相似文献
2.
Alfredo Ibáñez 《Review of Derivatives Research》2008,11(3):205-244
Existing evidence indicates that average returns of purchased market-hedge S&P 500 index calls, puts, and straddles are non-zero
but large and negative, which implies that options are expensive. This result is intuitively explained by means of volatility
risk and a negative volatility risk premium, but there is a recent surge of empirical and analytical studies which also attempt
to find the sources of this premium. An important question in the line of a priced volatility explanation is if a standard
stochastic volatility model can also explain the cross-sectional findings of these empirical studies. The answer is fairly
positive. The volatility elasticity of calls and puts is several times the level of market volatility, depending on moneyness
and maturity, and implies a rich cross-section of negative average option returns—even if volatility risk is not priced heavily,
albeit negative. We introduce and calibrate a new measure of option overprice to explain these results. This measure is robust
to jump risk if jumps are not priced.
相似文献
3.
The number of tailor-made hybrid structured products has risen more prominently to fit each investor’s preferences and requirements as they become more diversified. The structured products entail synthetic derivatives such as combinations of bonds and/or stocks conditional on how they are backed up by underlying securities, stochastic volatility, stochastic interest rates or exchanges rates. The complexity of these multi-asset structures yields lots of difficulties of pricing the products. Because of the complexity, Monte-Carlo simulation is a possible choice to price them but it may not produce stable Greeks leading to a trouble in hedging against risks. In this light, it is desirable to use partial differential equations with relevant analytic and numerical techniques. Even if the partial differential equation method would generate stable security prices and Greeks for single asset options, however, it may result in the curse of dimensionality when pricing multi-asset derivatives. In this study, we make the best use of multi-scale nature of stochastic volatility to lift the curse of dimensionality for up to three asset cases. Also, we present a transformation formula by which the pricing group parameters required for the multi-asset options in illiquid market can be calculated from the underlying market parameters. 相似文献
4.
Multi-stage real option evaluation with double barrier under stochastic volatility and interest rate
Annals of Finance - This paper focuses on valuing R&D projects using a twofold compound real option by including two knock-out barriers. However, the valuation of R&D projects is... 相似文献
5.
We develop a new approach for pricing European-style contingent claims written on the time T spot price of an underlying asset whose volatility is stochastic. Like most of the stochastic volatility literature, we assume
continuous dynamics for the price of the underlying asset. In contrast to most of the stochastic volatility literature, we
do not directly model the dynamics of the instantaneous volatility. Instead, taking advantage of the recent rise of the variance
swap market, we directly assume continuous dynamics for the time T variance swap rate. The initial value of this variance swap rate can either be directly observed, or inferred from option
prices. We make no assumption concerning the real world drift of this process. We assume that the ratio of the volatility
of the variance swap rate to the instantaneous volatility of the underlying asset just depends on the variance swap rate and
on the variance swap maturity. Since this ratio is assumed to be independent of calendar time, we term this key assumption
the stationary volatility ratio hypothesis (SVRH). The instantaneous volatility of the futures follows an unspecified stochastic
process, so both the underlying futures price and the variance swap rate have unspecified stochastic volatility. Despite this,
we show that the payoff to a path-independent contingent claim can be perfectly replicated by dynamic trading in futures contracts
and variance swaps of the same maturity. As a result, the contingent claim is uniquely valued relative to its underlying’s
futures price and the assumed observable variance swap rate. In contrast to standard models of stochastic volatility, our
approach does not require specifying the market price of volatility risk or observing the initial level of instantaneous volatility.
As a consequence of our SVRH, the partial differential equation (PDE) governing the arbitrage-free value of the contingent
claim just depends on two state variables rather than the usual three. We then focus on the consistency of our SVRH with the
standard assumption that the risk-neutral process for the instantaneous variance is a diffusion whose coefficients are independent
of the variance swap maturity. We show that the combination of this maturity independent diffusion hypothesis (MIDH) and our
SVRH implies a very special form of the risk-neutral diffusion process for the instantaneous variance. Fortunately, this process
is tractable, well-behaved, and enjoys empirical support. Finally, we show that our model can also be used to robustly price
and hedge volatility derivatives. 相似文献
6.
Efficient valuation of exchange options with random volatilities while challenging at analytical level, has strong practical implications: in this paper we present a new approach to the problem which allows for extensions of previous known results. We undertake a route based on a multi-asset generalization of a methodology developed in Antonelli and Scarlatti (Finan Stoch 13:269–303, 2009) to handle simple European one-asset derivatives with volatility paths described by Ito’s diffusive equations. Our method seems to adapt rather smoothly to the evaluation of Exchange options involving correlations among all the financial quantities that specify the model and it is based on expanding and approximating the theoretical evaluation formula with respect to correlation parameters. It applies to a whole range of models and does not require any particular distributional property. In order to test the quality of our approximation numerical simulations are provided in the last part of the paper. 相似文献
7.
The number of factors driving the uncertain dynamics of commodity prices has been a central consideration in financial literature. While the majority of empirical studies relies on the assumption that up to three factors are sufficient to explain all relevant uncertainty inherent in commodity spot, futures, and option prices, evidence from Trolle and Schwartz (Rev Financ Stud 22(11):4423–4461, 2009b) and Hughen (J Futures Mark 30(2):101–133, 2010) indicates a need for additional risk factors. In this article, we propose a four-factor maximal affine stochastic volatility model that allows for three independent sources of risk in the futures term structure and an additional, potentially unspanned stochastic volatility process. The model principally integrates the insights from Hughen (2010) and Tang (Quant Finance 12(5):781–790, 2012) and nests many well-known models in the literature. It can account for several stylized facts associated with commodity dynamics such as mean reversion to a stochastic level, stochastic volatility in the convenience yield, a time-varying correlation structure, and time-varying risk-premia. In-sample and out-of-sample tests indicate a superior model fit to futures and options data as well as lower hedging errors compared to three-factor benchmark models. The results also indicate that three factors are not sufficient to model the joint dynamics of futures and option prices accurately. 相似文献
8.
Jeff Fleming 《Journal of Empirical Finance》1998,5(4):317-345
This study examines the performance of the S&P 100 implied volatility as a forecast of future stock market volatility. The results indicate that the implied volatility is an upward biased forecast, but also that it contains relevant information regarding future volatility. The implied volatility dominates the historical volatility rate in terms of ex ante forecasting power, and its forecast error is orthogonal to parameters frequently linked to conditional volatility, including those employed in various ARCH specifications. These findings suggest that a linear model which corrects for the implied volatility's bias can provide a useful market-based estimator of conditional volatility. 相似文献
9.
This paper describes European-style valuation and hedging procedures for a class of knockout barrier options under stochastic
volatility. A pricing framework is established by applying mean self-financing arguments and the minimal equivalent martingale
measure. Using appropriate combinations of stochastic numerical and variance reduction procedures we demonstrate that fast
and accurate valuations can be obtained for down-and-out call options for the Heston model. 相似文献
10.
A new computational method for approximating prices of zero-coupon bonds and bond option prices under general Chan–Karolyi–Longstaff–Schwartz models is proposed. The pricing partial differential equations are discretized using second-order finite difference approximations and an exponential time integration scheme combined with best rational approximations based on the Carathéodory–Fejér procedure is employed for solving the resulting semi-discrete equations. The algorithm has a linear computational complexity and provides accurate bond and European bond option prices. We give several numerical results which illustrate the computational efficiency of the algorithm and uniform second-order convergence rates for the computed bond and bond option prices. 相似文献
11.
12.
Fast pricing of American-style options has been a difficult problem since it was first introduced to the financial markets in 1970s, especially when the underlying stocks’ prices follow some jump-diffusion processes. In this paper, we extend the ‘true martingale algorithm’ proposed by Belomestny et al. [Math. Finance, 2009, 19, 53–71] for the pure-diffusion models to the jump-diffusion models, to fast compute true tight upper bounds on the Bermudan option price in a non-nested simulation manner. By exploiting the martingale representation theorem on the optimal dual martingale driven by jump-diffusion processes, we are able to explore the unique structure of the optimal dual martingale and construct an approximation that preserves the martingale property. The resulting upper bound estimator avoids the nested Monte Carlo simulation suffered by the original primal–dual algorithm, therefore significantly improving the computational efficiency. Theoretical analysis is provided to guarantee the quality of the martingale approximation. Numerical experiments are conducted to verify the efficiency of our algorithm. 相似文献
13.
Friedrich Hubalek 《Quantitative Finance》2013,13(6):917-932
We introduce a variant of the Barndorff-Nielsen and Shephard stochastic volatility model where the non-Gaussian Ornstein–Uhlenbeck process describes some measure of trading intensity like trading volume or number of trades instead of unobservable instantaneous variance. We develop an explicit estimator based on martingale estimating functions in a bivariate model that is not a diffusion, but admits jumps. It is assumed that both the quantities are observed on a discrete grid of fixed width, and the observation horizon tends to infinity. We show that the estimator is consistent and asymptotically normal and give explicit expressions of the asymptotic covariance matrix. Our method is illustrated by a finite sample experiment and a statistical analysis of IBM? stock from the New York Stock Exchange and Microsoft Corporation? stock from Nasdaq during a history of five years. 相似文献
14.
Financial Markets and Portfolio Management - We propose a new unbiased robust volatility estimator based on extreme values of asset prices. We show that the proposed Add Extreme Value Robust... 相似文献
15.
Dirk Veestraeten 《Review of Derivatives Research》2017,20(1):1-13
The discounted stock price under the Constant Elasticity of Variance model is not a martingale when the elasticity of variance is positive. Two expressions for the European call price then arise, namely the price for which put-call parity holds and the price that represents the lowest cost of replicating the call option’s payoffs. The greeks of European put and call prices are derived and it is shown that the greeks of the risk-neutral call can substantially differ from standard results. For instance, the relation between the call price and variance may become non-monotonic. Such unfamiliar behavior then might yield option-based tests for the potential presence of a bubble in the underlying stock price. 相似文献
16.
This paper provides a comprehensive evaluation of the predictive ability of information accumulated during nontrading hours for a set of European and US stock indexes. We introduce a stochastic volatility model, which conditions on lagged overnight information, distinguishes between the nontrading periods of weeknights, weekends, holidays and long weekends, and allows for an asymmetric leverage effect on the impact of overnight news. We implement Bayesian methods for estimation and ranking of the empirical models, and find two key results: (i) there is substantial predictive ability in financial information accumulated during nontrading hours; and (ii) the performance of stochastic volatility models improves considerably by separating the asymmetric impact of positive and negative news made available over weeknights, weekends, holidays and long weekends. 相似文献
17.
18.
This paper compares the empirical performances of statistical projection models with those of the Black–Scholes (adapted to account for skew) and the GARCH option pricing models. Empirical analysis on S&P500 index options shows that the out-of-sample pricing and projected trading performances of the semi-parametric and nonparametric projection models are substantially better than more traditional models. Results further indicate that econometric models based on nonlinear projections of observable inputs perform better than models based on OLS projections, consistent with the notion that the true unobservable option pricing model is inherently a nonlinear function of its inputs. The econometric option models presented in this paper should prove useful and complement mainstream mathematical modeling methods in both research and practice. 相似文献
19.
We present a generalization of Cochrane and Saá-Requejo’s good-deal bounds which allows to include in a flexible way the implications of a given stochastic discount factor model. Furthermore, a useful application to stochastic volatility models of option pricing is provided where closed-form solutions for the bounds are obtained. A calibration exercise demonstrates that our benchmark good-deal pricing results in much tighter bounds. Finally, a discussion of methodological and economic issues is also provided. 相似文献
20.
Belén Nieto 《Journal of Banking & Finance》2011,35(9):2197-2216
This paper aims to assess the macroeconomic and financial impact of economic uncertainty using information contained in the second moments of financial risk factors employed in the asset pricing literature. Specifically, we propose the volatility of consumption-based stochastic discount factors (SDFs) as a predictor of future economic and stock market cycles. We employ both contemporaneous and ultimate consumption risk specifications with durable and non-durable consumption. Alternative empirical tests show that this volatility has significant forecasting ability from 1985 to 2006. The degree of predictability tends to dominate that shown by standard predictor variables. We argue that the significant predictability of the volatility of consumption-based SDFs reported in this paper relies mainly on the joint effect of their components. 相似文献