共查询到20条相似文献,搜索用时 15 毫秒
1.
Helmut Ziegelschmidt 《Empirica》1985,12(1):3-24
Zusammenfassung Die Frage, ob eine theoretisch plausible und im Zeitablauf stabile Geldnachfragefunktion empirisch nachgewiesen werden kann, nimmt einen wichtigen Platz in der aktuellen makroökonomischen Diskussion ein. Dies gilt insbesondere für diejenigen Länder, in denen sich die wirtschaftspolitischen Instanzen für eine Politik der Steuerung der Geldmenge entschieden haben.Doch auch für ein Land wie Österreich, wo aus verschiedenen Gründen andere geldpolitische Zwischenziele gewählt wurden, ist die Frage nach einem stabilen Zusammenhang von monetären Aggregaten und dem realen Sektor der Volkswirtschaft von Bedeutung: Eine Analyse geldpolitischer Vorgänge erlaubt nur dann verläßliche Rückschlüsse auf das nominelle Sozialprodukt, wenn die beobachteten Variablen in einer systematischen Beziehung zueinander stehen. Darüber hinaus verliert eine mögliche wirtschaftspolitische Strategie der Geldmengensteuerung von vornherein an Attraktivität, wenn berechtigte Zweifel an der Stabilität der Nachfrage nach Liquidität bestehen.In dem vorliegenden Beitrag werden Standardspezifikationen der Nachfrage nach Geld in verschiedenen Abgrenzungen geschätzt und auf ihre theoretische Plausibilität hin untersucht. Anschließend werden die geschätzten Geldnachfragefunktionen einer Reihe von Stabilitätstests unterzogen. Es zeigt sich, daß die Geldmenge M2 in der Definition des WIFO die statistischen Tests besonders gut besteht, doch auch die Nachfrage nach M1, vor allem in der Abgrenzung der Nationalbank, durch die gewählte Spezifikation bemerkenswert verläßlich erklärt werden kann.
The author wishes to thank Peter Sturm for helpful comments. The views expressed are not meant to represent those of the OECD Secretariat or its Member Governments. 相似文献
The author wishes to thank Peter Sturm for helpful comments. The views expressed are not meant to represent those of the OECD Secretariat or its Member Governments. 相似文献
2.
This paper develops a constant, data-coherent, equilibrium correction model for broad money demand (M3) in Greece over 1976–1994. The aggregate M3 was targeteduntil recently, and current monetary policy still uses such aggregates as guidelines. In spite of financial innovation, financial liberalization, and large fluctuations in the inflation rate, the estimated model is remarkabli stable. Dynamics are important, with price and income elasticities being much smaller in the short run than in the long run. The model provides a better understanding of the portfolio consequences of financial innovation and the effects of monetary policy in Greece.The authors are staff economists in the Division of International Finance, Federal Reserve Board, Washington, DC 20551 USA, and the Research Department, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC 20431 USA, respectively. They may be reached on the Internet at ericsson@frb.gov and ssharma@imf.org. The views expressed in this paper are solely the responsibility of the authors and should not be interpreted as reflecting those of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, the International Monetary Fund, or other members of their staffs. We wish to thank the Bank of Greece for providing the data; Sophocles Brissimis, Nicholas Paleocrassas, and George Simigiannis for offering insights into institutional aspects of the Greek financial system; and Richard Agénor, Caroline Atkinson, Adi Brender, Julia Campos, Dimitri Demekas, David Hendry, Katarina Juselius, Tim Lane, Helmut Lütkepohl, Jaime Marquez, Jürgen Wolters, and two anonymous referees for useful comments. An earlier version of this paper appeared as Ericsson and Sharma (1996). All numerical results were obtained using PcGive Professional Versions 8 and 9: see Doornik and Hendry (1994a, 1994b, 1996, 1997) and Hendry and Doornik (1996). The data may be obtained from the Internet, http://wotan.wiwi.hu-berlin.de/ oekonometrie/engl/data.html 相似文献
3.
4.
A money demand function for the Candian economy has been estimated to explore if recent financial innovations have caused any significant change in the structural relationship between the demand for money and its determinants. Two sets of estimation results have been analysed: the first set is obtained by estimating a standard money demand function for several overlapping sample periods and the other set is obtained by estimating a modified version which included a dummy or a ratchet variable to capture the effects of innovations. The estimated equations have been used to generate ex-post simulations and forecasts. The results suggest that innovations have displaced the money demand function in the early 1980s. It also appears that the incorporation of approriate innovation variables improves the predictive performance of the money demand function. 相似文献
5.
Matti Virén 《Applied economics》2013,45(11):1591-1596
This note presents some Finnish evidence on the importance of currency substitution and financial innovations for money demand. It is also shown that conventional demend for money specifications which do not take these factors into account are clearly misspecified and produced unreasonable results. The problem is particularly acute for narrow concepts of money. 相似文献
6.
Although there is general consensus on the determinants of the demand for money, the empirical performance of such money-demand equations has been unstable and poor in forecasting. In this study, the demand for money is empirically investigated on a disaggregated basis, by major sector, using Flow of Funds data, 1955i–1976iv. The results indicate that the empirical difficulties are specific to the corporate sector, that the problems in the corporate sector emerged during the later 1960s, and that foreign economic activity has become an important component in explaining holdings of cash by the corporate sector. 相似文献
7.
Brian Motley 《Journal of Macroeconomics》1979,1(4):395-403
In the General Theory, Keynes argued that expectations about future bond prices tend to be “sticky”. A rise in bond prices causes more investors to “join the bear brigade” and so increases the aggregate demand for money. Since Tobin's classic article on liquidity preference, this explanation of the downward sloping demand for money curve has largely disappeared from the literature. This note introduces sticky expectations into the Tobin framework. It shows that the existence of such stickiness does not necessarily cause the demand for money to be more elastic because investors have expectations about the variance of future bond prices as well as about their mean. A sufficient condition for a more elastic demand for money under sticky expectations is that the Pratt-Arrow coefficient of relative risk aversion be either constant or decreasing in wealth. 相似文献
8.
Julian Ramajo 《Applied economics》2013,45(6):771-782
The possibility of using time-varying parameter models in the context of error correction models is studied empirically. As an application, a money demand relationship (M1) for Venezuela is estimated from 1983 to 1994 within a cointegrated VAR framework. First, the stochastic properties of the series are analysed, studying each corresponding order of integration. Second, the existence of a long-run stable relation between the variables involved has been investigated, and then the cointegration relation and the short-run adjustment mechanism estimated. As both relations are identified in the context of constant parameters a stability analysis is performed. Finally, the technique of Kalman filtering is used to estimate a model that permits the short-run parameters to vary, while the parameters of the long-run relation are kept constant. 相似文献
9.
The purpose of this paper is to reconsider the work recently reported by Amihud that the demand for money is an increasing function of the risk of holding bonds. Our evidence from testing annual and quarterly Cambridge k and demand-for-money equations cannot confirm the positive and significant bond-yield uncertainty coefficient reported by Amihud in a semi-annual Cambridge k equation. 相似文献
10.
This paper tests the U.S. demand for money for evidence of the effect of rational expectations of the income and interest rate variables that enter as arguments into that function. The data employed are simple-sum and Divisia aggregates, and the nonparametric tests are of the identification and information orthogonality of the various monetary measures. The Akaike Criterion is used to distinguish among the alternative specifications. While non-rationality is the typical result, Divisia aggregates appear to be more “rational” than simple sum. There is evidence of mean-reversion in interest rates as well. 相似文献
11.
A panel data approach to the demand for money and the effects of financial reforms in the Asian countries 总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1
Alternative panel data estimation methods are used to estimate the cointegrating equations for the demand for money (M1) for a panel of 14 Asian countries from 1970 to 2005. The effects of financial reforms are analyzed with estimates for two sets of sub-samples and two break dates. Our results show that money demand function has been stable and financial reforms are yet to have any significant effects. Since there is no evidence for instability in the demand for money, the central banks of these countries should use money supply, instead of the rate of interest, as the monetary policy instrument. 相似文献
12.
Andreas M. Fischer 《European Economic Review》2007,51(7):1641-1660
Recent time-series evidence has re-confirmed the forecasting ability of Swiss broad money. The same money demand studies and others, however, find that the income elasticity is greater than one. Such parameter estimates are difficult to reconcile with transactions demand theory. This study re-examines the estimates for income elasticity in money demand based on cross-regional evidence for Switzerland. Particular attention is given to the influence of regional financial sophistication. The cross-cantonal results find that the income elasticity lies between 0.4 and 0.6. This discrepancy between the two empirical methodologies has important consequences for the conduct of Swiss monetary policy. 相似文献
13.
14.
15.
《Journal of development economics》1987,26(2):257-275
An empirical analysis of money demand behavior in Sudan is presented, based on the dynamic error-correction model. A theoretical basis for the model is offered, which allows an explicit, parameterized division of effects into long-run influences, short-term adjustments, and proportional equilibrium conditions. We refute previous claims that income and price effects may be abnormally high in Sudan, in part by accounting for both foreign exchange and inflationary influences. 相似文献
16.
The financial crisis has deeply affected money markets and thus, potentially, the proper functioning of the interest rate channel of monetary policy transmission. Therefore, we analyze the effectiveness of monetary policy in steering euro area money market rates by looking at (i) the predictability of money market rates on the basis of monetary policy expectations and (ii) the impact of extraordinary central bank measures on money market rates. We find that during the crisis money market rates up to 12 months still respond to revisions in the expected path of future rates, even though to a lesser extent than before August 2007. We attribute part of the loss in monetary policy effectiveness to money market rates being driven by higher liquidity premia and increased uncertainty about future interest rates. Our results also indicate that the ECB’s non-standard monetary policy measures as of October 2008 were effective in addressing the disruptions in the euro area money market. In fact, our estimates suggest that non-standard monetary policy measures helped to lower Euribor rates by more than 80 basis points. These findings show that central banks have effective tools at hand to conduct monetary policy in times of crises. 相似文献
17.
A small macroeconomic model is constructed starting from a German money demand relation for M3 based on quarterly, seasonally unadjusted data for the period from 1976 to 1996. In contrast to previous studies we build a vector error correction model for M3, GNP, an inflation rate and an interest rate spread variable to represent opportunity costs of holding money. Furthermore, import price inflation is added as an exogenous variable. The model is used to analyze the relation between money growth and inflation by means of an impulse response analysis.We thank Gerd Hansen for soliciting two anonymous referee reports on an earlier version of this article and thereby helping in the editorial process for this volume. We are grateful to him, Timo Teräsvirta, Kirstin Hubrich and the two referees for comments that helped us to improve our paper. Financial support was provided by the DFG, Sonderforschungsbereich 373. 相似文献
18.
AHMED M. KHALID 《Applied economics》2013,45(9):1129-1135
While early work on money demand estimation focused primarily on the importance of domestic variables, many studies in later years have suggested that foreign variables also influence the domestic demand for money in an open economy. With the rapid financial market liberalization in some of the Asian economies in the last couple of decades, open economy factors have become very important in the determination of money demand. Therefore, this paper aims to ascertain the degree to which foreign opportunity cost variables influence money demand in the Philippines, Singapore and South Korea. Cointegration analysis is performed and an error correction model estimated using quarterly time-series data. The empirical results support the inclusion of foreign opportunity cost variables in the money demand function. 相似文献
19.
20.
In this study we use disaggregated annual data to estimate real income and relative price elasticities of demand for imports of Venezuela. After comparing our estimates with those of previous studies, we conclude that (1) Venezuela has made progress in developing domestic substitutes for imports, and (2) the degree of ‘openness’ in Venezuela increased after 1961. We also find evidence that during the period 1974–1979, the increase in the market value of Venezuela's oil reserves led to an increase in all categories of imports. 相似文献