共查询到20条相似文献,搜索用时 15 毫秒
1.
Summary. Sustained endogenous growth is known to be impossible in OLG one-sector models without non-convexities and externalities,
unless income is redistributed to the young generation. No redistribution proper is however necessary, as shown in two simple
examples, if positive profits accruing to young monopolistic entrepreneurs can be sustained in equilibrium, and/or if young
unionised workers can guarantee a non-vanishing share of aggregate income. In this context, market power appears, in two different
forms, as a significant source of sustained endogenous growth.
Received: October 3, 2000; revised version: March 9, 2001 相似文献
2.
Summary. This paper studies the equilibria of a stochastic OLG exchange economies consisting of identical agents living for two periods,
and having the opportunity to trade a single infinitely-lived asset in constant supply. The agents have uncertain endowments
and the stochastic process determining the endowments is Markovian. For such economies, the literature has focused on studying
strongly stationary equilibria in which quantities and prices are functions of the exogenous states of nature which describe
the uncertainty: such equilibria are generalizations of deterministic steady states, and this paper investigates if they have
the same special status as asymptotic limits of other equilibrium paths. The difficulty in extending the analysis of equilibria
beyond the class of strongly stationary equilibria comes from the presence of indeterminacy: we propose a procedure for overcoming
this difficulty which can be decomposed into two steps. First backward induction arguments are used to restrict the domain
of possible prices; then if some indeterminacy is left, expectation functions are introduced to make the forward equilibrium
equations determinate. The properties of the resulting trajectories, in particular their asymptotic properties, can then be
studied. For the class of models that we study this procedure provides a justification for focusing on strongly stationary
equilibria. For the model with positive dividends (equity or land) the justification is complete, since we show that the strongly
stationary equilibrium is the unique equilibrium. For the model with zero dividends (money) there is a continuum of self-fulfilling
expectation functions resulting in a continuum of equilibrium paths starting from any admissible initial condition: under
conditions given in the paper, these equilibrium paths converge almost surely to one of the strongly stationary equilibria-either
autarchy or the stochastic analogue of the Golden Rule.
Received: November 19, 2001; revised version: March 22, 2002
RID="*"
ID="*" We are grateful for the stimulating environment and research support provided by the Cowles Foundation at Yale University
during the Fall 2000 when this paper was first conceived. We are also grateful to the participants of the SITE Workshop at
Stanford University and the Incomplete Markets Workshop at SUNY Stony Brook during the summer 2001 for helpful discussions.
Correspondence to: M. Magill 相似文献
3.
Klaus Ritzberger 《Economic Theory》2007,33(2):365-368
In general equilibrium models of imperfect competition the equilibria depend on how prices are normalized. This note shows
that a price normalization preserves convexity properties if and only if prices are measured in terms of a fixed commodity
bundle.
I am grateful to an anonymous referee for helpful comments, inspiring a simplification in the proof of the main result, and
the argument in the Remark. 相似文献
4.
Summary. We establish conditions under which indeterminacy can occur in a small open economy business cycle model with endogenous
labor supply. Indeterminacy requires small externalities in technologies with social constant returns to scale, independently
of the intertemporal elasticities in both consumption and labor.
Received: December 12, 2001; revised version: May 17, 2002
RID="*"
ID="*"The paper has benefited from discussions with Jess Benhabib and Mark Weder, as well as from the comments of an anonymous
referee.
Correspondence to: Q. Meng 相似文献
5.
Summary. General equilibrium models of oligopolistic competition give rise to relative prices only without determining the price level.
It is well known that the choice of a numéraire or, more generally, of a normalization rule converting relative prices into
absolute prices entails drastic consequences for the resulting set of Nash equilibria when firms are assumed to maximize profits.
This is due to the fact that changing the price normalization amounts to altering the objective functions of the firms. Clearly,
the objective of a firm must not be based on price normalization rules void of any economic content. In this paper we propose
a definition of the objective of a firm, called maximization of shareholders' real wealth, which takes shareholders' demand
explicitly into account. This objective depends on relative prices only. Real wealth maxima are shown to exist under certain
conditions. Moreover, we consider an oligopolistic market and prove the existence of a Nash equilibrium in which each firm
maximizes the real wealth of its shareholders.
Received: July 10, 1997; revised version: July 27, 1998 相似文献
6.
Julio Dávila 《Economic Theory》2003,22(1):169-192
Summary. This paper shows new properties about the equilibria of a stationary OG economy by establishing a connection between its
stationary equilibria and those of a finite economy, with and without extrinsic uncertainty. Specifically, it shows the countability
and local uniqueness with respect to the sup metric of the so-called sunspot cycles introduced here, that encompass both the
deterministic cycles and the usual finite Markovian stationary sunspot equilibria. These sunspot cycles are, moreover, able
to generate, at a lower cost in terms of assumptions than other sunspot equilibria, time series with the recurrent but irregular
fluctuations typical of economic time series.
Received: July 26, 2001; revised version: March 5, 2002
RID="*"
ID="*" I want to thank an anonymous referee for comments that have helped greatly to improve this paper, as well as the comments
about its contents received from several audiences in different seminars and conferences (the Economic Theory seminar of the
University of Pennsylvania, the 2001 Meeting of the Econometric Society held at New Orleans, the 2000 Econometric Society
World Congress, the 2000 Society for Economic Design Conference) and from comments to a previous paper, Dávila [10], specially
from Jim Peck at the 1997 Workshop on General Equilibrium held at the University of Venice, that eventually lead to this one. 相似文献
7.
Summary. We consider a discrete-time two-sector Cobb-Douglas economy with positive sector specific external effects. We show that
indeterminacy of steady states and cycles can easily arise with constant or decreasing social returns to scale, and very small
market imperfections. This is in sharp contrast with most of the contributions in the literature in which increasing social
returns are required to generate indeterminacy.
Received: July 31, 2000; revised version: June 5, 2001 相似文献
8.
Gabrielle Demange 《Economic Theory》2002,20(1):1-27
Summary. This paper defines and studies optimality in a dynamic stochastic economy with finitely lived agents, and investigates the
optimality properties of an equilibrium with or without sequentially complete markets. Various Pareto optimality concepts
are considered, including interim and ex ante optimality. We show that, at an equilibrium with a productive asset (land) and sequentially complete markets, the intervention
of a government may be justified, but only to improve risk sharing between generations. If markets are incomplete, constrained
interim optimality is investigated in two-period lived OLG economies. We extend the optimality properties of an equilibrium with
land and give conditions under which introducing a pay-as-you-go system at an equilibrium would not lead to any Pareto improvement.
Received: October 5, 1998; revised version: April 3, 2001 相似文献
9.
Summary. We consider a linear exchange economy and its successive replicas. We study the notion of Cournot-Walras equilibrium in which
the consumers use the quantities of commodities put on the market as strategic variables. We prove that, generically, if the
number of replications is large enough but finite, the competitive behaviour is an oligopoly equilibrium. Then, under a mild
condition, which may be interpreted in terms of market regulation and/or market activity, we show that any sequence of oligopoly
equilibria of successive replica economies converges to the Walrasian outcome and furthermore that every oligopoly equilibrium
of large, but finite, replica is Pareto optimal. Consequently, under the same assumptions on the fundamentals of the economy,
one has an asymptotic result on the convergence of oligopoly equilibria to the Walras equilibrium together with a generic
existence result for the Cournot-Walras.
Received: June 20, 2002; revised version: November 20, 2002
RID="*"
ID="*" Part of this paper was written while the second author was visiting the Universidad de Vigo. The support of the department
of mathematics is gratefully acknowledged.
Correspondence to: J.M. Bonnisseau 相似文献
10.
We study a simple bilateral oligopoly model in which individual agents, who are initially endowed with capital, decide sequentially (1) whether they want to act as producers (entrepreneurs) or as capital lenders (rentiers) and, then (2) which quantity of capital they would like to borrow or lend, though exchange of capital units against units of the produced good. Production takes place under increasing returns to scale. We show the existence of “natural equilibria”, at which wealthier capital owners become entrepreneurs while the remaining ones decide to be rentiers. We also study the efficiency of equilibria which is shown to increase by replication of the economy, but sometimes to decrease as a consequence of wealth redistribution.We thank an anonymous referee for his insightful comments 相似文献
11.
Summary. This paper considers electoral competition between two office-motivated parties and one voter, in the presence of two alternative policies and under imperfect information. The theory of refinements of Nash equilibrium predicts the outcome of this three-player game: both parties faithfully use their information and try to find the best policy for the voter. We discuss the meaning of this model for Politics and prove that the same result holds for any number of voters, provided that parties are expected plurality maximizers and that voters satisfy a version of the sincere voting assumption adapted to this strategic setting.Received: 12 December 2001, Revised: 16 June 2003JEL Classification Numbers:
C72, D72, D82.Correspondence to: Jean-François LaslierThanks to Gabrielle Demange, Françoise Forges, Roger Guesnerie, Jean-Fran çois Mertens, Thomas Palfrey, Sylvain Sorin and other participants in workshops and conferences in Caen, Paris, Caltech and Yale. Thanks also to two anonymous referees and to Paul Heidues and Johan Lagerlöf for their comments. This work was originated when K. Van der Straeten was at THEMA (Université de Cergy-Pontoise) and DELTA. 相似文献
12.
The economic effects of restrictions on government budget deficits: imperfect private credit markets
Summary. The present paper is an extension of Ghiglino and Shell [7] to the case of imperfect consumer credit markets. We show that
with constraints on individual credit and only anonymous (i.e., non-personalized) lump-sum taxes, strong (or “global”) irrelevance
of government budget deficits is not possible, and weak (or “local”) irrelevance can hold only in very special situations.
This is in sharp contrast to the result for perfect credit markets. With credit constraints and anonymous consumption taxes,
weak irrelevance holds if the number of tax instruments is sufficiently large and at least one consumer's credit constraint
is not binding. This is an extension of the result for perfect credit markets.
Received: August 28, 2001; revised version: March 25, 2002
RID="*"
ID="*" We thank Todd Keister, Bruce Smith, and two referees for helpful comments.
Correspondence to: C. Ghiglino 相似文献
13.
The welfare cost of imperfect competition in the product and labor markets in the United States is quantified in a dynamic general equilibrium model. We find that the welfare cost of imperfect competition in the product market is 3.62 percent while it is 0.58 percent in the labor market, taking the transition path from the distorted to the optimal steady state into account. If we also take into account that the US economy is characterized by distortionary taxation, the welfare cost of the product market distortion increases to 13.51 percent and the labor market distortion to 4.35 percent. 相似文献
14.
Summary. We consider a model of political competition among two ideological parties who are uncertain about the distribution of voters.
The distinguishing feature of the model is that parties can delegate electoral decisions to candidates by nomination. It is
shown that if the credible platform commitments of the candidates is feasible, then at least one of the parties nominates
in equilibrium to a candidate who has an ideology that is more radical than the delegating party's ideology. In a variety
of circumstances, this, in turn, yields a polarization of equilibrium policy choices of the candidates. It is thus argued
formally here that strategic nomination of the candidates may well be one of the major reasons behind the well documented
observation that the platforms associated with the political parties in two-party democracies are often surprisingly polarized.
Received: January 10, 2002; revised version: May 8, 2002
RID="*"
ID="*" We thank Alberto Alesina, Levent Ko?kesen, Antonio Merlo, Ronny Razin, Vijay Krishna, Alessandro Lizzeri, and seminar
participants at Alicante, Columbia, Copenhagen, and NYU for helpful comments. We also thank an anonymous referee for its useful
suggestions. A good fraction of this research was conducted while Ok was a visitor in the Department of Economics at University
of Alicante; he thanks for the kind hospitality of this institution. We gratefully acknowledge the financial support from
the Spanish Ministry of Education through grant CICYT BEC2001-0535 (Faulí-Oller) and BEC2001-0980 (Ortu?o-Ortín).
Correspondence to:I. Ortu?o-Ortin 相似文献
15.
Summary. We analyze an oligopoly model of homogeneous product price competition that allows for discontinuities in demand and/or costs.
Conditions under which only zero profit equilibrium outcomes obtain in such settings are provided. We then illustrate through
a series of examples that the conditions provided are “tight” in the sense that their relaxation leads to positive profit
outcomes.
Received: April 7, 2000; revised version: September 14, 2000 相似文献
16.
Bruno Decreuse 《Economic Theory》2001,17(2):481-488
Summary. In this paper, we provide an altruistic interpretation to the Blanchard (1985) perpetual youth model and examine under which
conditions such interpretation holds. Unlike the standard model, the modified model essentially requires no insurance and
a bequest nonnegativity constraint.
Received: March 25, 1999; revised version: May 3, 2000 相似文献
17.
Rationing rule, imperfect information and equilibrium 总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1
Roger Waldeck 《Economic Theory》2002,19(3):493-507
Summary. The impact of imperfect information on the price setting behaviour of firms is analysed. Specifically, consumers support
an information cost to become informed about prices. Firms are endowed with U-shaped average cost curves. If a firm does not
supply more than its competitive supply as determined by its marginal cost schedule, then we show that the existence of a
pure strategy equilibrium is conditional on the rationing rule employed. If uninformed consumers are served first then the
monopoly price is the sole equilibrium whenever consumers' information costs are high enough. Otherwise, a pure strategy equilibrium
fails to exist contrary to the results of Salop and Stiglitz (1977) or Braverman (1980) who implicitly suppose that firms
supply all the demand at a given price.
Received: May 17, 1999; revised version: September 15, 2000 相似文献
18.
Camelia Bejan 《Economic Theory》2008,37(1):99-118
This paper proposes a model of imperfect competition among privately owned firms that act in the best interest of their shareholders.
The existence of a solution for the model is proved under weaker conditions than the ones generally used in the literature.
In particular, the results did not require the existence of a continuous equilibrium price selection or concavity assumptions
on the profit function.
相似文献
19.
Hans Gersbach 《Economic Theory》1999,14(3):729-740
Summary. This paper analyzes how monetary policy in an overlapping generations model can be designed to avoid inflationary consequences
of anticipated changes of monetary policies. Avoiding these inflationary consequences will require a once and for all increase
(decrease) in monetary growth immediately before the policy switch takes place if the relative risk aversion is greater (less)
than unity. If the relative risk aversion is greater than unity, the avoidance of inflationary consequences is also time-consistent.
Moreover, a general monetary feedback rule ensures that the economy picks the steady state with the lowest inflation rate.
Our results suggest that the difference between unanticipated and anticipated policy switches may not be as important as generally
assumed, because the consequences of the latter can be neutralized.
Received: September 19, 1995; revised version: July 27, 1998 相似文献
20.
Tetsuo Ono 《Economic Theory》2003,22(1):141-168
Summary. The purpose of this paper is to consider environmental taxation which would control emissions of firms in a model of growth
cycles. In the model presented below, the economy may experience two phases of growth and environmental quality: “the no-innovation
growth regime” and “the innovation-led growth regime”. Aggregate capital and environmental quality remain constant in the
no-innovation growth regime, while they perpetually increase in the innovation-led growth regime. The paper shows that the
tax plays a key role in determining whether the economy stably converges to one of the two regimes or fluctuates permanently
between them. It also shows that there is a critical level of the tax and that the economy obtains higher growth rates of
capital and environmental quality by raising (or reducing) the tax if the initial tax is below (or above) the critical level.
Received: April 2, 2001; revised version: March 21, 2002
RID="*"
ID="*" This research reported here was conducted within the research project “Project on Intergenerational Equity” at Institute
of Economic Research, Hitotsubashi University. I am deeply grateful to an anonymous referee for his or her insightful comments,
which greatly improved the paper. I also thank Hiroshi Honda, Yasuo Maeda, Yuji Nakayama, and participants in workshops at
Hitotsubashi University, Kyoto University, Nagoya University, Osaka University, University of Tsukuba, Yokohama National University,
and University of Tokyo for their valuable comments and suggestions. Any remaining errors are mine. 相似文献