共查询到20条相似文献,搜索用时 0 毫秒
1.
We find that Federal Reserve Bank presidents’ regional bias in their dissenting interest rate votes in the Federal Open Market Committee follows an electoral cycle. Presidents put more weight on their district’s economic environment during the year prior to their (re-)election relative to nonelection years. 相似文献
2.
We study competition between political parties in repeated elections with probabilistic voting. This model entails multiple equilibria, and we focus on cases where political collusion occurs. When parties hold different opinions on some policy, they may take different policy positions that do not coincide with the median voter's preferred policy platform. In contrast, when parties have a mutual understanding on a particular policy, their policy positions may converge (on some dimension) but not to the median voter's preferred policy. That is to say, parties can tacitly collude with one another, despite political competition. Collusion may collapse, for instance, after the entry of a new political party. This model rationalizes patterns in survey data from Sweden, where politicians on different sides of the political spectrum take different positions on economic policy but similar positions on refugee intake—diverging from the average voter's position, but only until the entry of a populist party. 相似文献
3.
We study whether and to what extent the electoral dynamics in Italy over the 1994–2008 period can be explained by the development of economic factors associated with globalization. To measure the level of exposure to globalization for local labor markets, our main unit of analysis, we use the intensity of import competition from China and the presence of immigrants. Looking at parties’ political positions and employing an estimation strategy that accounts for endogeneity and time‐invariant unobserved effects across local labor markets, we find that both immigration intensity and exposure to import competition from China have contributed positively to the electoral outcomes of far‐right parties, whereas only immigration intensity has increased the vote shares of right‐wing and traditionalist/authoritarian/nationalist parties. Some evidence, albeit not robust, shows that immigration may have also had a positive impact on far‐left parties, thus possibly further contributing toward political polarization. Moreover, electoral turnout has responded negatively to an increased presence of migrants. While the above effects seem to work through the mediation of labor markets, our results, especially those related to immigration, suggest that other mechanisms at the level of local communities are also at play. 相似文献
4.
Do voters respond to political parties׳ promises or to their past actions? We use a suitable sequence of events in Swedish politics to provide the first answer to this question. In the 1994 election campaign the Social Democrats proposed major cuts in transfers to parents with young children, whereas in the 1998 campaign they promised to increase transfers. The Social Democrats won both elections and delivered on both promises. Using voting among parents with slightly older children as counterfactual, we find that voters with young children responded markedly to economic promises rather than to implemented policies. 相似文献
5.
回顾了单层次(即微观及宏观层次)的责任制研究,梳理了现有的多层次责任制研究,重点探讨了国外学者提出的多层次责任制研究模型。最后指出现有研究存在的不足,并展望了未来的研究方向。 相似文献
6.
Recent events highlight primary type as an institutional variable that merits further examination in the economics literature
on voter turnout. Using panel data for U.S. gubernatorial elections and treating primary type as a proxy for candidate deviation
from the median voter, we test whether primary type changes voter turnout and whether that change is dominated by instrumental
or expressive voting. The results show that states with more open primaries tend to have greater voter turnout in general
elections, and that this increase reflects the effect of open primaries on expressive voting.
相似文献
Christopher WestleyEmail: |
7.
借鉴一般性政治投票机制,并结合公司治理目的及其利益主体特性,提出两种改进公司治理投票机制的方案——可转移的累积投票和贮存式投票,并对这两种改进方案的积极意义进行评估和分析。最后,对公司治理投票机制优化设计的后续研究问题进行了展望。 相似文献
8.
In costly voting models, voters abstain when a stochastic cost of voting exceeds the benefit from voting. In probabilistic voting models, they always vote for a candidate who generates the highest utility, which is subject to random shocks. We prove an equivalence result: In two-candidate elections, given any costly voting model, there exists a probabilistic voting model that generates winning probabilities identical to those in the former model for any policy announcements, and vice versa. Thus many predictions of interest established in one of the models hold in the other as well, providing robustness of the conclusions to model specifications. 相似文献
9.
政府责任内涵的广泛性和本质的复杂性,导致了其在实现过程中遭遇的一系列困境,同时也催生了若干责任追究机制的产生和逐渐演进。从行政问责制到高官问责制,体现了政府责任诉求在制度层面的逻辑演进经历了制度内涵、价值原则以及制度程序的深化与聚集,这使得政府责任的实现路径日渐清晰。 相似文献
10.
Electoral competition with policy-motivated candidates 总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1
In the multi-dimensional spatial model of elections with two policy-motivated candidates, we prove that the candidates must adopt the same policy platform in equilibrium. Moreover, when the number of voters is odd, if the gradients of the candidates' utility functions point in different directions, then they must locate at some voter's ideal point and a strong symmetry condition must be satisfied: in particular, it must be possible to pair some voters so that their gradients point in exactly opposite directions. If the number of dimensions is more than two, then our condition is knife-edge. When the number of voters is even, the situation is worse: such equilibria never exist, regardless of the dimensionality of the policy space. 相似文献
11.
管理层问责:后国企改革时代的新课题 总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1
改革开放以来,我国国企改革取得了令人瞩目的成就,但仍未能从根本上革除国企绩效低下、所有者缺位、内部人控制等弊端。在依次经历扩大企业自主权、从经营权向所有权过渡、推进建立现代企业制度和深化国家控股股份公司(特别是上市公司)内部改革等四个阶段之后,我国已进入到后国企改革时代。从委托代理的视角来看,产权制度改革后的国企仍然存在多级委托代理关系,这是单纯的产权制度改革并不能解决国企顽疾的症结之所在。在后国企改革时代要根除国企诸多弊病,必须从深层次推动国企改革,重点是加强对管理层的约束和监管,切实建立和完善有效的管理层问责机制。 相似文献
12.
Frederic Vermeulen 《Applied economics》2013,45(9):1089-1092
In Heien and Wessells (1990), a two-step estimation procedure, that makes use of Heckman-type corrections, is proposed to estimate consumption on household budget surveys. It is shown that this approach, which draws from switching regressions models, leads to inconsistent estimates. 相似文献
13.
Leo H. Kahane 《Applied economics》2020,52(33):3574-3587
ABSTRACT County-level data are used to estimate the incumbent-party share of the two-party vote in the 2012 and the 2016 U.S. Presidential elections. Using a ‘seemingly unrelated estimation’ procedure the regression results for the two elections show that there were some clear differences in the size of marginal effects for several key covariates. For example, income inequality, the size of the black male and black female populations, the size of the Hispanic male population and percent of the population with a college degree all had significantly larger coefficients in 2016 than in 2012, producing a larger marginal effect in favour of the Democratic candidate’s vote share. On the other hand, counties with increased poverty rates and counties located on the periphery of urban centres had a significantly larger marginal effect favouring the Republican’s vote share in 2016 compared to 2012. Finally, the regression results show that the effects of third-party vote shares, though not statistically different across the two elections, had a positive impact on the Democratic vote share in both elections. 相似文献
14.
The major premise of this study is that in federal countries voters can balance and moderate national policy by dividing electoral support between different parties in federal and sub-national elections. We compare the non-concurrent federal and provincial elections in Canada to assess the balancing properties of sub-national elections. The balancing hypothesis implies that the federal incumbent party may suffer additional electoral losses in provincial elections. We use several statistical tests - ordinary OLS, fixed effect and unbalanced random effect cross-section time series - to analyze Canadian electoral data for the period of 1949-1997. All tests sustain that the incumbent party at the federal level loses votes in provincial elections. 相似文献
15.
自2003年因SARS风暴引起的政府问责事件以来,在政治社会生活中,对政府问责的制度设计和制度实践渐趋成形,但由于以造成严重损害后果为导向的、党政系统内的同体问责制度设计不当,从而限制了政府问责制度应有的功能。这种狭义上的政府问责制度,同样规范和制约着乡镇政府问责,乡镇政府作为我国政府层级体系中的最基层组织,与农民有着最为紧密的联系,其主要职责是对农村公共事务的管理。探索建立科学、合理、全面的乡镇政府问责制度,不仅为乡镇政府职权的规范行使,满足农民的利益诉求,提供切实保障;同时也为与此相关的基层民主政治建设,提供制度支持。 相似文献
16.
Dennis C. Mueller 《Constitutional Political Economy》2001,12(2):161-172
Almost all of economic theorizing takes individual preferences as givens, and then proceeds to analyze individuals' choices within the constraints that they face. This paper takes into account the fact that preferences are to some extent endogenous, and that the state typically plays an important role in shaping individual preferences through its education and other policies. It analyzes the consequences of assuming both exogenous and endogenous preferences, and homogeneous and heterogeneous preferences for the choice between centralized and decentralized (federalist) government structures. Given the increasingly heterogeneous nature of individual preferences, more decentralized, federalist structures are deemed likely to be optimal. Ironically, at the same time an increasing tendency to proclaim and impose cross nationally a set of universal values can be discerned. 相似文献
17.
To allow society to treat unequal alternatives distinctly we propose a natural extension of Approval Voting by relaxing the assumption of neutrality. According to this extension, every alternative receives ex-ante a strictly positive and finite weight. These weights may differ across alternatives. Given the voting decisions of every individual (individuals are allowed to vote for, or approve of, as many alternatives as they wish to), society elects the alternative for which the product of total number of votes times exogenous weight is maximal. If the product is maximal for more than one alternative, a pre-specified tie-breaking rule is applied. Our main result is an axiomatic characterization of this family of voting procedures. 相似文献
18.
We model expressive voting as a dynamic game with informed and ignorant voters. A voter has selective memory for actions and he is aware of it. We find a unique symmetric equilibrium with ignorant voting. Public signal in favor of one particular alternative creates the bandwagon and underdog effects. When the signal is sufficiently strong, the majority outcome is biased. This is a possible reason for persistence of public policies. 相似文献
19.
The Political Economy of Social Security 总被引:4,自引:0,他引:4
Georges Casamatta Helmuth Cremer & Pierre Pestieau 《The Scandinavian journal of economics》2000,102(3):503-522
We consider a two-period overlapping generations model in which individual voters differ by age and by productivity. In such a setting, a redistributive pay-as-you-go system is politically sustainable, even when the interest rate is higher than the rate of population growth. The workers with medium wages (not those with the lowest wages) and the retirees form a majority which votes for a positive level of social security. This level depends on the difference between the rates of population growth and interest as well as on the redistributiveness of the benefit rule. 相似文献
20.
Petra GerlachKristen 《The Scandinavian journal of economics》2004,106(2):299-313
It is shown that the voting record of the Monetary Policy Committee of the Bank of England helps predict future policy rate changes. This result is robust to the inclusion of market participants’ expectations as measured by the slope of the term structure of money market rates and interest rate futures. Moreover, expectations seem to adjust to the information contained in the voting record, which suggests that publishing the minutes of MPC meetings increases the transparency of monetary policy. 相似文献