共查询到20条相似文献,搜索用时 9 毫秒
1.
We consider the microfoundations controversy from the perspectiveof economic evolution. Although the analogy between biologyand economics has been noted before, it has rarely focused onclarifying the micromacro distinction in economic theoryand modelling. The micromacro debate is more developedin biology than in economics owing to a greater degree of specialisationand a greater degree of interaction between various sub-disciplines.The task for economists is to distinguish between insights directlyrelevant for economic theory and ones that hinge on unique featuresof biological systems. We argue that both micro and macro processesdrive economic change and that macroeconomic change cannot beexplained by microlevel optimising alone. We show that debatesin biology about group selection and punctuated equilibria arerelevant to understanding economic evolution. The oppositionof reductionism and holism is of little use and, in its place,a hierarchical approach is proposed. This allows for both upwardand downward causation and interaction between levels. 相似文献
2.
Florian Botte 《Journal of post Keynesian economics》2019,42(2):232-254
The article presents an original stock-flow consistent macroeconomic agent-based model with the aim to reexamine Harrod’s instability principle as an explanatory element of macroeconomic dynamics. The main findings are that bottom-up economic models can be subject to Harrodian instability and can produce endogenous cycles without introducing innovation waves, monetary wage spirals, or financial instability. Upward instability is stopped by the ceiling of full employment, and downward instability can be tamed by introducing an autonomous expenditure that feeds aggregate demand. 相似文献
3.
The Review of Austrian Economics - The Austrian School interpretation of the Keynes-Hayek debate runs counter to the conventional wisdom that Hayek “lost” the debate. Austrians maintain... 相似文献
4.
This paper studies the role of entry and exit in the short run behavior of a general equilibrium model with industry dynamics. For tractability, and to preserve potential asymmetries in the impulse responses, I focus on the transition dynamics of the economy after shocks. Entry and exit are found to be insensitive to productivity shocks of reasonable magnitude. Moreover, the dynamics of GDP are insensitive to fluctuations in entry and exit rates, and any asymmetries are negligible. As an application of the model, the paper also asks whether firing costs may interact with entry and exit to affect transition dynamics after shocks, finding that they do not. 相似文献
5.
Norikazu Takami 《European Journal of the History of Economic Thought》2013,20(2):203-215
Abstract This note examines A. C. Pigou's views on the practical issue of high unemployment in the 1920s. In his Industrial Fluctuations, Pigou emphasized that the monetary aspect of business cycles was much more important to fluctuations in unemployment than wage adjustment. In a journal article, however, he stated that major part of the high unemployment should be attributed to the failure of money wage adjustment. I argue that, on balance, Pigou attached greater importance to monetary problems than to the wage rigidity. 相似文献
6.
This article estimates two unobserved components models to explore the macrodynamics of entrepreneurship in Spain and the USA. We ask whether entrepreneurship exhibits hysteresis, defined as a macrodynamic structure in which the cyclical component of entrepreneurship has persistent effects on the natural rate of entrepreneurship. We find evidence of hysteresis in Spain, but not the USA, while in Spain business cycle output variations significantly affect future rates of entrepreneurship. The article discusses implications of the findings for the design of entrepreneurship policies. 相似文献
7.
In this paper, we propose a temporal disaggregation model with regime switches to disaggregate U.S. quarterly GDP into monthly figures. Alternative to the existing literature, our model is able to capture the nonlinear behaviors of both aggregated and disaggregated output series as well as the asymmetric nature of business cycle phases. To demonstrate the applicability of the proposed model, we apply the model with a Markov trend component to U.S. quarterly real GDP. The results suggest that the combination of a temporal disaggregation model with Markov switches leads to a successful representation of the data relative to the existing literature. Also, the inferred probabilities of unobserved states are clearly in close agreement with the NBER reference cycle on a monthly basis, which highlights the importance of nonlinearities in business cycle. 相似文献
8.
There is considerable evidence that the density of basic innovations is peaked at definite periods with intervals of about 40–60 years. This has been used as support for the behavior of economic cycles as postulated by Kontradieff and amplified by Schumpeter. Recently some economists have used this model to forecast economic recovery in the middle or late 1980s.This paper points out that the shape of the clusters of innovation or inventions are different and sharper than those of economic depression or economic recovery. The transfer of knowledge from basic inventions to industrial innovations shortens as one moves from the 18th to the 20th century, and some probable explanations for this are offered. The importance of discoveries and limited discoveries to the process of invention and innovation is discussed. Also shown is that discoveries reveal cluster phenomena which are functionally related to the clusters of invention and innovation. 相似文献
9.
Abstract This paper documents some previously neglected features of sectoral shares at business cycle frequencies in OECD economies. We find that the non‐traded output share is as volatile as aggregate GDP and for most countries is countercyclical. While the standard international real business cycle model has difficulty in accounting for these properties of the data, an extended model that allows for sectoral adjustment along both the intensive and the extensive margins does a much better job of replicating these statistics. The model also matches better the correlation between relative consumption growth and real exchange rate changes, a key measure of international risk‐sharing. 相似文献
10.
This paper develops and tests the predictions of two open economy models in which partisan effects are present, a small-country-one-good model of exchange rate determination and a model that assumes the two countries each specialize in the production of one good. From these models, we can obtain predictions for the behaviour of the terms of trade, the current account, and real and nominal exchange rates. The predictions are tested empirically using panel data from 14 OECD countries and the results provide support for the theoretical predictions that systematic partisan effects are present in current accounts, real exchange rates, and the terms of trade. 相似文献
11.
12.
13.
《Review of Economic Dynamics》2006,9(3):455-482
There are substantial differences in business cycle fluctuations across countries. These differences are systematically related to the share of agriculture in the economy: Countries with a high share of employment in agriculture feature high fluctuations in aggregate output, low relative volatility of aggregate employment, and low correlation of aggregate output and employment. In addition, agriculture has certain distinctive features over the business cycle: Output and employment in agriculture are more volatile than and not positively correlated with output and employment in the rest of the economy and output and employment are less correlated in agriculture than in non-agriculture. Because of these features, agriculture may play a role in accounting for aggregate business cycles across countries. We calibrate an otherwise standard two-sector indivisible-labor business cycle model with agriculture and non-agriculture to aggregate and sectoral data for the United States. We find that an increase in the employment to population ratio in agriculture from 2 to 30 percent in our model increases fluctuations in aggregate output by almost 40 percent. This is about 2/3 of the difference in aggregate fluctuations between countries such as Turkey and the United States. 相似文献
14.
Shih-Chang HungAuthor Vitae Yu-Chuan Hsu Author Vitae 《Technological Forecasting and Social Change》2011,78(7):1104-1114
Understanding the correlation between the crystal cycle and the business cycle is important, because it can help managers to anticipate change, reduce environmental uncertainty, and formulate operational objectives. To this end, we focused on China and the U.S. in our analysis. We found that the economic indicators that were the most relevant in the characterization of China's huge and burgeoning TFT-LCD market are gross domestic production and industrial production. We complemented this finding by conducting similar analyses in the U.S. market using a more comprehensive list of economic indicators. 相似文献
15.
The recent financial crisis highlighted the need to deepen our understanding of the impact of the financial intermediation sector on the real economy. We examine the quantitative implications of financial intermediation and firm's financing frictions in explaining the observed cyclical properties of both real and financial variables. We find that a modified version of the financial intermediation framework of Gertler and Karadi (2011) augmented with financing frictions in production does a good job in matching the unconditional moments of financial fluctuations without compromising key real co-movements. Our results are relevant for macro-prudential policy analysis as they underscore the importance of carefully identifying the sources of aggregate fluctuations in models in which financial intermediaries and financial frictions play a non-trivial role. 相似文献
16.
Summary. This incorporates a debt contracting problem with asymmetric information into a standard monetary business cycle model. The
model incorporates a limited participation assumption in order to induce a liquidity effect of monetary shocks and propagate
monetary disturbances. The model economy shows that a positive money supply shock generates a decrease in nominal interest
rates and an increase in output level. Asymmetric information amplifies the response of capital to the money supply shock,
but does not propagate them in other ways. When the monetary shock is an innovation in reserve requirements, it induces a
persistent response of the economy.
Received: March 20, 1998; revised version: 1 April 1998 相似文献
17.
This paper studies the long-run relationship between consumption, asset wealth and income—the consumption–wealth ratio—based
on German data from 1980 to 2003. We find that departures from this long-run relationship mainly predict adjustments in income.
The German consumption–wealth ratio also contains considerable forecasting power for a range of business cycle indicators,
including the unemployment rate. This finding is in contrast to earlier studies for some of the Anglo-Saxon economies that
have shown that the consumption–wealth ratio reverts to its long-run mean mainly through subsequent adjustments in asset prices.
While the German consumption wealth ratio contains little information about future changes in German asset prices, we report
that the U.S. consumption–wealth ratio has considerable forecasting power for the German stock market. One explanation of
these findings is that in Germany—due to structural differences in the financial and pension systems—the share of publicly
traded equity in aggregate household wealth is much smaller than in the Anglo-Saxon countries. We discuss the implications
of our results for the measurement of a potential wealth effect on consumption.
The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors and do not reflect the position of the Deutsche Bundesbank. We
gratefully acknowledge comments and suggestions from an anonymous referee as well as from Heinz Herrmann, Helmut Lütkepohl,
the editor, Baldev Raj, Burkhard Raunig, Monika Schnitzer, Harald Uhlig and Christian Upper. We also benefitted from comments
by seminar participants at the ECB, the Deutsche Bundesbank, the CESifo Macro, Money and International Finance Area Conference
2005, the EEA 2005 annual congress and at the 2005 IAEA Meetings. Last but not least, we would like to thank Mark Weth for
very useful information concerning the construction of the financial wealth data. Hoffmann’s work on this paper is also part
of the project The International Allocation of Risk funded by Deutsche Forschungsgemeinschaft in the framework of SFB 475. Responsibility for any remaining errors and shortcomings
is entirely our own. 相似文献
18.
In the time domain, the observed cyclical behavior of the real wage hides a range of economic influences that give rise to
cycles of differing lengths and strengths. This may serve to produce a distorted picture of wage cyclicality. Here, we employ
frequency domain methods that allow us to assess the relative contribution of cyclical frequency bands on real wage earnings.
Earnings are decomposed into standard and overtime components. We also distinguish between consumption and production wages.
Frequency domain analysis is carried out in relation to wages alone and to wages in relation to output and employment cycles.
Our univariate analysis suggests that, in general, the dominant cycle followed by output, employment, real consumer and producer
wages and their components is 5–7 years. Consistent with previous findings reported in the macro-level literature, our bi-variate
results show that the various measures of the wage are generally not linked to the employment cycle. However, and in sharp
contrast with previous macro-level studies we find strong procyclical links between the consumer wage and its overtime components
and the output cycle, especially at the 5–7 years frequency.
Observed real wages are not constant over the cycle, but neither do they exhibit consistent pro- or counter-cyclical movements. This suggests that any attempt to assign systematic real wage movements a central role in an explanation of business cycles is doomed to failure. (lucas 1977)相似文献
19.
This paper estimates a New Keynesian model extended to include heterogeneous expectations: consumers and firms form either rational or boundedly-rational expectations. The inclusion of heterogeneous expectations alters the determinacy properties of the model, with the details of expectations potentially becoming more influential than the Taylor principle for equilibrium stability.The model is estimated with Bayesian techniques, using rolling windows and allowing the parameters to fall both in the determinacy and indeterminacy regions. The estimates reveal large shares of agents who depart from rational expectations. Heterogeneous expectations are decisively preferred by the data everywhere in the sample.Finally, the paper revisits the narrative that sees postwar US macroeconomic data as consistent with indeterminacy in the pre-1979 sample, with a switch to determinacy starting in the early 1980s, and it shows that it is overall robust to inclusion of heterogeneous expectations. 相似文献
20.
Zi‐Yi Guo 《Review of International Economics》2020,28(1):209-234
We introduce a noisy information structure into an otherwise standard international real business cycle model with two countries. When domestic firms observe current foreign technology with some noise, predictions of the model on international correlation can be very different from those of a standard perfect information model. We show that the model can explain: (a) positive output correlation both in complete and incomplete market models, (b) consumption correlation smaller than output correlation with an introduction of information‐constrained consumers, and (c) observation of both positive and negative productivity–hours correlation in two countries. 相似文献