共查询到20条相似文献,搜索用时 0 毫秒
1.
We propose an ex-post analysis of the behavior of a central bank confronted with financial turmoil. For this purpose, we rely on a DSGE model that combines credit market frictions with a boom and bust scenario on the price of capital. Within this framework, we seek to understand the extent to which central banks could have intervened to limit the effects of the financial bubble and its bursting. We compare the results obtained in terms of economic stabilization under a simple Taylor rule with those of an augmented rule that takes into account a financial indicator. We show that a central bank using as sole instrument the interest rate cannot simultaneously improve inflation and credit cycles. 相似文献
2.
Rob Euwals 《De Economist》2000,148(5):643-670
The Dutch mandatory pension system consists of two parts: a public pay-as-you-go part that provides a minimum income to all Dutch inhabitants over age 64 and an occupation-specific capital-funded part that provides supplementary retirement income. The goal of this paper is to test for the effect of mandatory pensions on discretionary household savings. The data are drawn from the CentER Savings Survey. A result of the empirical analysis is that the impact of the public part of the Dutch pension system is not well identified. The occupational pensions have a significant negative impact on savings motives with respect to old age. The evidence on the effect on household wealth is mixed. 相似文献
3.
Atlantic Economic Journal - This paper shows that so-called modern monetary theory (MMT) lacks a sound economic foundation for its far-reaching policy recommendations. This paper’s main... 相似文献
4.
This paper examines empirically whether central bank capital influences the conduct of monetary policy. To this end, we estimate interest rate rules for a sample of 41 countries and employ linear and non-linear regression methods to test if a measure of central bank financial strength can explain deviations of actual interest rates from those predicted by the estimated interest rate (Taylor-like) rules. Our results suggest that central bank capital is indeed a relevant factor behind interest rate policy decisions. 相似文献
5.
Long term projections for the Netherlands indicate that demand for nontradables—e.g. health care services—will increase relative to supply due to population ageing. If this leads to higher future real exchanges rates this will erode the return of the savings currently made to prepare for ageing. This paper explores the magnitude of potential price effects using a modified version of the two country, four commodity framework developed by Obstfeld and Rogoff (Brookings Papers Econ Activity 1:67–146, 2005) to explore the exchange rate effects of the balance of payments reversal in the US. When these price effects are substantial this may have serious consequences for policies to enhance national saving in the Netherlands. 相似文献
6.
7.
Abstract To understand how the macro economy evolves, the central bank has two options in choosing how to estimate the economic model against actual data: one is to estimate each sector of the model piece-by-piece, and the other is to estimate the whole model altogether. This paper demonstrates the advantage for the central bank of estimating the whole model in terms of the estimation accuracy and the robustness of the resulting policy recommendations. For that aim, we construct a macro model for the monetary policy analysis of the Korean economy and estimate the model via the system approach and single-equation approach. We evaluate the data fits of the two estimation results and show that the fit of the system approach is far better than the other and comparable to other methods such as vector autoregressions. It is also shown that, if the two estimated models are equally likely, conducting the policy tailored for the model estimated by the system approach delivers better stabilization results for the Korean economy. 相似文献
8.
9.
Why does the Monetary Policy Committee smooth interest rates? 总被引:2,自引:0,他引:2
Explanations of why the monetary authorities in different countriesseem to smooth interest rates have focused on the official dislikeof financial market volatility, aspects of the decision-makingprocess, responses to uncertainty, inertial behaviour in a forward-lookingenvironment, and serial correlation of shocks to the policymakers'expectations. This paper first shows that policy has been smoothestand comparable to that in other countries in the period of inflationtargeting with Bank of England control of interest rates since1997. It then uses the remarkably detailed evidence availablefrom the minutes of the Monetary Policy Committee to evaluatethe relevance of the various explanations of smoothing for theUK in this period. The paper concludes that the explanationof interest rate smoothing should be sought primarily in theserial correlation of shocks, together with some minor and short-terminfluences from uncertainty, while the other explanations turnout to be not relevant. 相似文献
10.
Willem H. Buiter 《Open Economies Review》2007,18(2):127-156
The paper discusses some fundamental problems in monetary economics associated with the determination and role of the numéraire.
The issues are introduced by formalising a proposal, attributed to Eisler, to remove the zero lower bound on nominal interest
rates by unbundling the numéraire and medium of exchange/means of payment functions of money. The monetary authorities manage
the exchange rate between the numéraire (‘sterling’) and the means of payment (‘drachma’). The short nominal interest rate
on sterling bonds can then be used to target stability for the sterling price level. The paper puts question marks behind
two key bits of conventional wisdom in contemporary monetary economics. The first is the assumption that the monetary authorities
define and determine the numéraire used in private transactions. The second is the proposition that price stability in terms
of that numéraire is the appropriate objective of monetary policy. The paper also discusses the merits of the next step following
the decoupling of the numéraire from the currency: doing away with currency altogether—the cashless economy. Because the unit
of account plays such a central role in New-Keynesian models with nominal rigidities, monetary economics needs to devote more
attention to numérairology—the study of the individual and collective choice processes that govern the adoption of a unit of account and its role in
economic behaviour.
相似文献
Willem H. BuiterEmail: Email: URL: http://www.nber.org/˜wbuiter/ |
11.
This paper assesses the fiscal sustainability of ten Eurozone member countries at a national and aggregate level. It is carried out in light of the relevant literature on monetary unions and the framework of the European Monetary Union vis-à-vis the current sovereign debt crisis. The impact of Eurobonds, which are considered as a viable solution, on fiscal sustainability was empirically tested. The results indicate that only three countries appear to be structurally sustainable whereas the majority of the countries are only sustainable in the short-run and two countries are structurally unsustainable. However, the sustainability of the Eurozone is greatly improved when the Eurobonds are used. 相似文献
12.
Joshua Aizenman 《Open Economies Review》2018,29(2):373-382
We take stock of the history of the European Monetary Union and pegged exchange-rate regimes in recent decades. The post-Bretton Woods greater financial integration and under-regulated financial intermediation have increased the cost of sustaining a currency area and other forms of fixed exchange-rate regimes. Financial crises illustrated that fast-moving asymmetric financial shocks interacting with real distortions pose a grave threat to the stability of currency areas and fixed exchange-rate regimes. Members of a currency union with closer financial links may accumulate asymmetric balance-sheet exposure over time, becoming more susceptible to sudden-stop crises. In a phase of deepening financial ties, countries may end up with more correlated business cycles. Down the road, debtor countries that rely on financial inflows to fund structural imbalances may be exposed to devastating sudden-stop crises, subsequently reducing the correlation of business cycles between currency area’s members, possibly ceasing the gains from membership in a currency union. A currency union of developing countries anchored to a leading global currency stabilizes inflation at a cost of inhibiting the use of monetary policy to deal with real and financial shocks. Currency unions with low financial depth and low financial integration of its members may be more stable at a cost of inhibiting the growth of sectors depending on bank funding. 相似文献
13.
Developing countries traditionally experience pass-through of exchange rate changes that is greater and more rapid than high-income
countries experience. This is true equally of the determination of prices of imported goods, prices of local competitors’
products, and the general CPI. But developing countries in the 1990s experienced a rapid downward trend in the degree of pass-through
and speed of adjustment, more so than did high-income countries. As a consequence, slow and incomplete pass-through is no
longer exclusively a luxury of industrial countries. Using a new data set—prices of eight narrowly defined brand commodities,
observed in 76 countries—we find empirical support for some of the factors that have been hypothesized in the literature,
but not for others. Significant determinants of the pass-through coefficient include per capita incomes, bilateral distance,
tariffs, country size, wages, long-term inflation, and long-term exchange rate variability. Some of these factors changed
during the 1990s. Part (and only part) of the downward trend in pass-through to imported goods prices, and in turn to competitors’
prices and the CPI, can be explained by changes in the monetary environment—including a fall in long-term inflation. Real
wages work to reduce pass-through to competitors’ prices and the CPI, confirming the hypothesized role of distribution and
retail costs in pricing to market. Rising distribution costs, due perhaps to the Balassa-Samuelson-Baumol effect, could contribute
to the decline in the pass-through coefficient in some developing countries. 相似文献
14.
Open Economies Review - We evaluate monetary policy divergence in the G4. A Taylor rule is extended that admits a global element and also allows for unconventional monetary policy to be reflected... 相似文献
15.
This paper aims to find a suitable definition of a low skilledworker, that can be applied in a consistent way across the variouscountries of the European Union. The International StandardClassification of Education (ISCED) is identified as the mostsuitable means of measuring skills over time and space, as thoseindividuals categorised as less than ISCED 3 are labelled low-skilled.The paper then uses three international surveys of educationalperformance to justify this choice. It is shown that those inthe <ISCED 3 group are likely to have a limited grasp ofthe skills needed in the modern workplace, and that this definitionalgroup captures most individuals who are categorised as low-skilledby more objective means. Thus this definition of low-skilledworkers appears to be useful and appropriate. 相似文献
16.
Key findings in behavioral economics are that people’s behavior (revealed preferences) is often not in line with their intentions
(normative preferences), that they are sensitive to the way choices are presented to them, and that their cognitive abilities
are limited. This is manifest in particular in areas of intertemporal choice, like personal finance and health-related behavior.
Policy makers can develop policies that help citizens to make choices that are more in line with their normative preferences.
In this paper we summarize the behavioral evidence, discuss the motivations for interventions, and show how recent behavioral
insights can help to improve upon existing policies. These new policies could be described as libertarian paternalism, and
include setting defaults thoughtfully and using unorthodox commitment mechanisms. 相似文献
17.
Open Economies Review - Policymakers in emerging markets complained that the unconventional US monetary policy response to the Great Recession hurt their economies. US policymakers responded that... 相似文献
18.
19.
Akhand Akhtar Hossain 《Journal of Asian Economics》2010,21(6):564-578
Since the mid-1980s Bangladesh has implemented a loose form of monetary targeting under two exchange-rate régimes: a pegged system until May 2003 and a ‘managed floating’ exchange-rate system. Under both régimes, broad money has been used as an intermediate target to maintain price stability, which implies as the ultimate goal a relatively low and stable rate of inflation. Inflation in this country has, however, remained moderately high and volatile, especially during the 1970s under the pegged exchange-rate system. With the apparent ineffectiveness of the monetary-targeting system in achieving price stability, even following the 2003 ‘managed float’ of the currency, there has been some suggestion that it should be replaced by, say, inflation targeting. This paper forms an element of a fuller study of the issue. It investigates the behaviour of broad money demand in Bangladesh using annual data over the period 1973–2008. Empirical results suggest that an open-economy broad money demand function has remained stable in Bangladesh since the early 2000s. Empirical results also suggest the existence of a causal relationship between money supply growth and inflation. The paper concludes that, although monetary targeting remains appropriate for Bangladesh, its implementation can be made more effective in stabilising the price level if the Bangladesh Bank enhances its control over the money supply by eschewing nominal exchange-rate stabilisation through foreign exchange market interventions. 相似文献
20.
André Van Poeck 《De Economist》2010,158(1):43-60
In this paper we analyze whether the ECB’s monetary policy has become more balanced towards the needs of the individual member
states with the passage of time. We assume that the ECB’s monetary policy stance is in line with a Taylor rule and based on
the overall situation in the Euro area, more specifically on the Euro area inflation rate and the overall business cycle position
in the area. The question therefore boils down to investigating whether inflation and business cycles have converged since
the start of the monetary union. We show that the ECB, if in existence in the 1990s, would have had an impossible task. This
is because inflation and business cycles still strongly differed in that time, although convergence substantially increased
in the run up to the monetary union. In this respect, the decade under EMU drastically differs from the preceding one. This
being said, the evidence for a further improvement in the course of the first decade of the new millennium is mixed. This
is because although inflation has further converged, business cycles have shown a tendency for increased divergence. If, however,
we are willing to put weights on inflation and output gap divergence (as implied by the Taylor rule), we conclude that also
in the course of the period under EMU in general the ECB’s monetary policy has become more in line with the needs of the individual
members. Looking at individual countries, we show that during the first decade of its existence the ECB’s interest rate was
most fitted to the needs of France and Italy, and least to the needs of Ireland and Greece (both too low) and Germany (too
high). To a lesser extent there were also mismatches for Spain and Portugal (both too low). In the more recent period since
2005, the mismatch between the desired domestic interest rate and the desired ECB rate has come down for most countries (most
noticeable Germany). For Belgium (for which a higher interest rate was more appropriate), on the other hand, the mismatch
increased. These overall positive findings, however, offer no guarantee that the task of the ECB will become easier in the
future. 相似文献