共查询到20条相似文献,搜索用时 0 毫秒
1.
One of the common tasks of the development planner is to decide on the placing of services and amenities in order to enhance the life opportunities of people. The mere provision of amenities may, however, have little or no utility value. Amenities must be accessible to the people they are intended for and the authors suggest that too little attention is being paid by development planners to factors which inhibit accessibility. Traditionally, access has been viewed as a function of distance, but it is also affected by socio‐economic and cultural factors. A recent study of Merebank is used to highlight these issues. 相似文献
2.
Relative income position,individual and social income satisfaction,and income inequality 总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1
A. L. Hempenius 《De Economist》1984,132(4):468-478
Summary The survival probability as estimated by an individual is,ceteris paribus supposed to depend on his relative income position in a set of reference incomes. The relative income position is thus defined
in close connection to the preference formation theory of Kapteyn. It is shown that then this survival probability, called
‘utility,’ may be equated to the relative income position. A nice result of this approach is the possibility to formulate
a utilitarian welfare function, which leads to the definition of income inequality measures. It is shown that the use of sets
of reference incomes may lead to considerably smaller measured inequality. 相似文献
3.
Rank, income and income inequality in urban China 总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1
While some workers in China attain senior professional level and senior cadre level status (Chuzhang and above), others attain middle rank including middle rank of professional and cadre (Kezhang). This aspect of the Chinese labour force has attracted surprisingly little attention in the literature, a fact which this paper aims to rectify. We define various segments of the urban population in work-active ages and use data from the Chinese Income Project (CHIP) covering eastern, central and western China for 1995 and 2002. For 2002, persons of high rank make up 3% and persons of middle rank make up 14% of persons in work-active ages.Factors that affect a person's likelihood of having high or middle rank are investigated by estimating a multinomial probit model. We find that education, age and gender strongly affect the probability of being employed as a worker of high rank. There is relatively little income inequality among workers of high rank as well as among workers of middle rank. Mean income and household wealth per capita of highly-ranked workers developed more favorably than for other segments of the population studied, and personal income is more polarized by segment in 2002 than in 1995. Workers of high rank, and to a lesser degree, workers of middle rank, are among the winners in economic terms while the increasingly large category of non-workers is the losers. Rates of return to education have increased but income function analysis indicates that this provides only a partial explanation for the increased favorable income situation for workers of high and middle ranks. 相似文献
4.
5.
Customer discrimination may result in racial differences in the marginal revenue products generated by workers. College basketball
data allow for direct comparisons of the racial differences in the marginal revenues generated by players. This article compares
the revenue generating potential of the top black and white college basketball players. A highly skilled white college player
generates over $100,000 in per game revenues as compared to around $30,000 for a black player of equal talent, providing a
strong incentive for colleges to discriminate against recruiting black student-athletes. 相似文献
6.
7.
8.
改革个人所得税,增大调节收入分配的力度 总被引:2,自引:0,他引:2
一、改革个人所得税的理论支持 根据边际消费倾向递减规律,富人越富越有钱他的边际消费倾向越小,反之,穷人越穷,边际消费倾向越大。收入差距的过大使较大比重的社会财富沉淀在少数人手中,很多有消费欲望的人却无力购买,只好降低边际消费倾向,可见进行收入再分配缩短贫富差距对于刺激消费需求的重要意义。 相似文献
9.
10.
11.
12.
Rodney D. Green Marie Kouassi Belinda Mambo 《The Review of Black Political Economy》2013,40(2):145-163
The destruction of private and public housing in New Orleans caused by Hurricane Katrina was greatest among African Americans due to historic settlement patterns. Data for 13 planning districts within Orleans Parish (the city of New Orleans proper) that document the extent of housing destruction, the distribution of population by race, and the share of returned population at 2 and 5 year points across these planning districts are evaluated using correlation analysis. The finding is that the return of African Americans to New Orleans is significantly less than that of other groups and is associated with the greater housing destruction in neighborhoods with the highest percentages of African Americans. An analysis of the structure and impact of the Road Home program for private housing and of the initiatives of the U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development and the Housing Authority of New Orleans provides evidence of racial discriminatory policies and practices that contributed to the racial disparity in the African American return to New Orleans. It is suggested that political leaders paid more attention to the interests of developers and big businesses in the restoration of New Orleans than to the interests of the predominantly black working class in the city. 相似文献
13.
14.
15.
ASEAN FTA,distribution of income,and globalization 总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1
Danupon Ariyasajjakorn James P. Gander Somchai Ratanakomut Stephen E. Reynolds 《Journal of Asian Economics》2009,20(3):327-335
This paper examines the impact of Free Trade Agreements on income distribution within the Association of Southeast Asian Nations (ASEAN) and between the members and their trading partners outside ASEAN. The study uses a Computable General Equilibrium model, a modified version of the 57 sector, 87 country, Global Trade Analysis Project (GTAP) integrated model of national input–output tables, version-6.2 (2001 database) with its reserve matrix facility, to simulate income distribution results as an outcome of certain parameter changes that appear in intra and inter regional trade.Within ASEAN, trade liberalization will stimulate the output of each country within the region according to their comparative advantage. Since trade liberalization tends to increase output of capital-intensive goods more than labor-intensive goods, the less-developed countries within the region tend to get smaller benefits compared to other member countries. In addition, the physical means of production tend to gain more relative to the gains of labor from the FTAs. This tends to widen the income gap between high-income and low-income households within ASEAN.Comparing ASEAN and the developed non-ASEAN countries, an FTA within ASEAN tends to reduce the returns to labor of the developed non-member countries and narrow the income gap between ASEAN, as a whole, and those rich countries since capital-intensive products of developing countries are often labor-intensive goods of developed countries. 相似文献
16.
Various types of basic income schemes are considered to compensatethe allocative inefficiencies induced by unemployment benefits.A dynamic general equilibrium model of a unionised economy isdeveloped in which participation to the formal labour marketis endogenous and the budget of the State has to balance. Itis shown that basic income schemes reduce the equilibrium unemploymentrate. Assuming that job-search is costly to monitor, the normativeanalysis suggests that only the active population should beeligible to the basic income. Introducing such an activecitizens income can be a Pareto-improving reform. 相似文献
17.
Hans Gersbach 《Review of World Economics》1999,135(2):221-240
Product Market Competition, Unemployment and Income Disparities. — We discuss how promoting competition in product markets affects unemployment and wage differentials. We examine a general equilibrium model with real wage rigidities in labor markets and market power in product markets. We illustrate how more intense competition reduces unemployment. A decrease of markups would induce an increase of real wages if real wages were flexible. This enables the employment of more low-skilled people above a real reservation wage. More intensive competition, however, widens wage and income differences between low-skilled and high-skilled workers. Differences of income distributions across countries could also be caused by differences in the intensity of product market competition. 相似文献
18.
19.
Jim Rose 《Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics》1998,1(4):75-87
Conclusion We are no longer limited to qualitative discussions of the merits of a social clause in the GATT against child labor. Future debates should be in quantitative terms. Child labor can contribute up to 25 percent of family income-contributions that the ILO regards as critical to their survival. Child laborers have few alternatives if they lose their jobs as a result of a social clause on labor standards. It is reasonably clear that child labor falls away quickly with economic development. However, multilateral trade agreements against child labor such as those proposed for inclusion in the WTO (and ILO) do not promote economic development. The contrary is more likely to be the case: they may reduce the range of alternatives available to children and their parents as producers, consumers, and breadwinners in developing countries. 相似文献
20.
One of the most heated scholarly controversies in the area of racial equality and social justice in the 1980s has been the dispute over the nature, cause, and meaning of economic changes occurring within the black community. Although this debate has important public policy consequences, most of the research on which the debate is based is concerned with income. We argue that a broader interpretation of life chances should include an examination of wealth as well as income. Using the 1984 Survey of Income and Program Participation (SIPP), we examine black and white patterns of wealth inequality. Our analysis uncovers a depth of inequality beyond that which is found when income alone is considered. Furthermore, we find that both race and class are important in determining patterns of racial inequalities in wealth. 相似文献