共查询到20条相似文献,搜索用时 15 毫秒
1.
This paper considers the links between trade liberalization and technology choice in the nonliberalizing country. Trade‐liberalization‐induced changes in relative product prices have direct effects on equilibrium relative factor returns. The consequent changes in relative input costs may also lead producers to switch to alternative technologies, which will in turn induce a further indirect change in relative factor returns. Will this indirect affect exacerbate or ameliorate the direct effect on relative factor returns? It is found that this depends on the relative cost savings across sectors and factor cost shares. 相似文献
2.
Can reduced trade barriers promote a collusive understanding about not exporting into each others domestic markets? Reduced trade costs increase the short‐run gains from starting exporting, but can also make the long‐run punishment of such a strategy harsher. If collusion on prices is supported by a trigger strategy, a reduction in trade costs weakens competition in the sense that collusion is easier to sustain. In a corresponding model with collusion on quantities, this conclusion is reversed. The authors also discuss how results change if grim trigger strategies are replaced by stick‐and‐carrot punishments. 相似文献
3.
4.
Professor Keith Blackburn 《International economic journal》2013,27(1):33-46
We develop an endogenous growth model in which trade liberalization has a positive effect on growth. This effect does not depend on marginal re-allocations nor on knowledge-spillovers. Rather, it is due solely to the increase in market size following the integration of product markets. Our result contradicts a widely-help view that trade on physical goodsper sehas no consequences for long-run growth.[F15] 相似文献
5.
A computable general equilibrium model of Egypt is developed to analyze proposed reforms in its trade policies, including a partnership agreement with the European Union. The model has multiple trading regions and allows for administrative trade barriers and tariffs. The paper reports computations of the revenue impacts of trade liberalization and the required changes in distortionary commodity taxes to maintain a fixed real government budget. Egypt's greatest potential gains come from removing its administrative trade barriers while adopting globally free trade. The partnership agreement with the EU could lower or raise Egypt's welfare, depending on prior trade reform. 相似文献
6.
中间品贸易自由化与中国制造业企业生产技术选择 总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1
《经济研究》2016,(8):72-85
本文在异质性企业分析框架下,构建了贸易自由化下中间品进口与企业技术选择的理论模型,分析了中间品贸易自由化对企业技术选择的影响机理,并利用2000—2006年中国制造业企业数据考察了中间品贸易自由化对中国制造业企业技术选择的影响。实证结果表明,入世后,中间品贸易自由化显著促进了中国制造业出口企业应用高技术。进一步考虑企业生产率差异性时,发现这种促进作用与企业的初始生产率水平有关,仅仅显著促进中等生产率的企业进行技术升级。另外,中间品贸易自由化对技术密集型出口企业技术升级的促进作用最强,对劳动密集型出口企业技术选择的影响最弱。 相似文献
7.
1.引言近十年的经验研究表明,标准的新贸易理论对于同质厂商的假设忽略了许多现实的重要因素。例如,并非所有的厂商都在贸易部门进行贸易,而且同一部门内的出口厂商的生产力一般要高于该部门的非出口厂商(A.W,Chung和Roberts 2000,Bernard和Jensen 1995,1999a,b,2001;Clerides,Lach和Tybout 1998;Eaton,Kortum和Kramarz 2004;参见Tybout 2003 for a survey)。 相似文献
8.
Kenji Fujiwara 《Environmental and Resource Economics》2009,44(1):71-84
We build a two-country differential game model of polluting oligopoly to consider the effects of trade liberalization. As in static models, the opening of trade promotes competition but expands global pollution. Characterizing open-loop and feedback strategies, we derive a sufficient condition for losses from trade. This losses-from-trade proposition could provide a rationale for persistent resistance to globalization by environmentalists. 相似文献
9.
Horst Raff 《Review of International Economics》2001,9(3):455-461
Suppose a country imports a homogeneous good from n foreign countries/producers and wants to eliminate tariffs on imports from m < n of them. If foreign producers differ in their marginal costs, which ones will be among the m that are granted free trade? This paper shows, among other things, that under constant marginal cost and fairly general assumptions about demand it will be the least efficient producers. 相似文献
10.
在国际贸易自由化的背景下,我国企业面临着较大的生存压力.探讨企业在这种贸易环境下生存发展的一种途径,即在其业务结构中增加服务供应的比重,从而更好地适应市场的变化,这被称为制造业的服务化.利用上市制造企业数据的计量结果表明,较低的制造业进口关税导致企业从商品生产转向服务供应,贸易自由化推动并实现了我国企业转型.而通过机制分析还发现,在关税降低的背景下,制造企业将其生产活动进行海外外包并非是其实现服务化转型的关键,企业研发能力的打造才是贸易自由化背景下推动企业业务模式变革的重要影响因素,由于研发强度本身就是企业比较优势的来源,因此这也符合赫克歇尔-俄林的理论机制. 相似文献
11.
12.
Joseph Francois 《经济资料译丛》2005,(3):59-67
原载:European Journal0f Political Economy Vol.595(2001)[《欧洲政治经济学杂志》2001年第595卷]一、概述自建立以来,多边贸易体系一直只关注货物贸易。因此,从1947到东京回合,服务在历次的贸易谈判中都未曾提及。乌拉圭回合及其后世界贸易组织的成立,改变了这种状况。通过服务贸易总协定(GATS),他们将服务引进并纳入到多边贸易体系中。然而,实际的自由化程度一直相对较低,GATS的许多减让表还只是简单地停留在承诺上(或者连承诺都谈不上)。所以人们普遍认为服务部门的自由化仍有很大的发展空间。本文关心的是服务部门自由化的解析… 相似文献
13.
Incorporating pollution emissions from international transportation into a model of strategic trade and environmental policies, we investigate the effect of trade liberalization and environmental regulation on national welfare and the environment. Our model includes imperfectly competitive markets for international transportation and final products. We find that trade liberalization may reduce each country's welfare unless some level of environmental regulation on international transportation is in place. When international trade is liberalized initially, a mutual increase in the common emission tax rates may improve each country's welfare. However, when international trade is highly protected initially, imposing an emission tax may reduce welfare. 相似文献
14.
Alain-Désiré Nimubona 《Environmental and Resource Economics》2012,53(3):323-346
During the Doha Round at the World Trade Organization, reductions in trade barriers on environmental goods (EG) were put forward as a means of helping developed and developing countries alike deal with current environmental problems. We examine the potential effectiveness of such a strategy in a developing country that imports all its consumption of EG from an imperfectly competitive foreign eco-industry. We point out that trade liberalization of EG might in fact lead to less stringent pollution taxes, which can result in an actual rise in pollution levels. We then show that the environmental effectiveness objective of this trade reform can be achieved when the regulator uses quantitative abatement standards as an alternative pollution policy instrument. However, this environmental achievement comes at the expense of social welfare. 相似文献
15.
加入WTO以后,我国与其他国家的贸易将进一步自由化,本将探讨由此将给我国环境带来的可能后果以及我国应采取的对策。笔认为贸易自由化主要是通过规模效应、结构效应及技术创新等作用对一国的环境产生影响。应利用贸易自由化有利于环境的因素,限制不利于环境的因素,使我国的环境状况得到优化。 相似文献
16.
17.
Takumi Naito 《Review of Development Economics》2000,4(2):164-174
A two-final-good, one-primary-factor, small–open endogenous growth model is constructed based on R&D. The model yields two steady states with different growth rates as potential equilibria. Depending on history and the external environment, the economy may fall into the poverty trap in free trade. However, a temporary trade policy can release the economy from the poverty trap. Moreover, the optimal trade policy is gradual trade liberalization with the rate of protection kept to a minimum. 相似文献
18.
Yu-Bong Lai 《Environmental and Resource Economics》2006,34(2):269-290
In considering a country that imposes a minimum standard on an imported polluting good, which generates negative consumption
externalities, we construct a common-agency model, in which a domestic environmental group and a foreign industrial lobby
can influence the formation of the minimum standard by providing political contributions to the government. This paper investigates
the effects of trade liberalization on the political equilibrium environmental standard, the pattern of trade, environmental
disutility, and social welfare. We find that trade liberalization tightens the minimum standard, decreases imports of the
polluting good, and reduces environmental disutilities. The importing country’s social welfare, however, does not necessarily
increase with trade liberalization. The weaker the environmental group’s lobbying efficiency, or the stronger the foreign
firm’s lobbying efficiency, the more likely it is that trade liberalization will enhance the importing country’s welfare. 相似文献
19.
Hans Jarle Kind 《Review of International Economics》2002,10(1):151-165
The paper combines insight from new trade theory and R&D-based endogenous growth models to argue that there are ambiguous growth effects of trade liberalization between countries that differ in terms of the size of their home markets. In particular, trade liberalization may reduce R&D incentives in countries with low purchasing power without invoking parallel increases in countries with high purchasing power. The paper also considers the case of imperfect international knowledge spillovers, and demonstrates that complete trade liberalization may affect the growth rate negatively. 相似文献
20.
NICHOLAS GRUEN 《The Economic record》1999,75(4):385-396
Despite the frequency with which they have been promoted as a model of development. East Asian trade policies have had little influence on the normative economics of trade reform. In contrast to directly dismantling protection, developing countries have often provided concessional import rights which override existing protection. These instruments include EPZs and duty remission. This paper accommodates these instruments of 'new trade liberalization' within a more general understanding of trade liberalization illustrating their similarities and their differences. Both old and new trade liberalization can, on their own, bring about complete free trade. Needless to say, so far, neither has! 相似文献