共查询到20条相似文献,搜索用时 15 毫秒
1.
2.
3.
Income Inequality,Human Capital,and Income Growth: Evidence from a State-Level VAR Analysis 总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1
Mark W. Frank 《Atlantic Economic Journal》2009,37(2):173-185
We use Granger causality and impulse response analysis to examine the relationship between income inequality, human capital
attainment, and income growth using annual state-level data over the period 1929–2000. We find consistent evidence that the
income share of the top decile Granger-causes income growth, but only weak evidence that income growth Granger-causes the
top decile income share. Moreover, an impulse response analysis indicates that income growth responds negatively to permanent
changes in the income share of the top decile. These findings appear to have important regional variations, however, with
the more densely populated Eastern states showing the strongest associations. We also find evidence that years of schooling
may Granger-cause income levels, but little evidence that years of schooling Granger-causes the top decile income share.
相似文献
Mark W. FrankEmail: |
4.
文章从国际垂直分工引起贸易增长的视角研究中国收入分配不平等问题。文章认为,垂直专业化使得贸易扩张和收入在不同部门之间的分配产生差异,最后导致收入不平等的扩大。 相似文献
5.
Dong Jin Lee 《Global Economic Review》2016,45(4):331-358
This paper empirically investigates the effect of income inequality on economic growth using extended panel data covering a broad range of developing and developed countries. We use system generalized method of moments (GMM) techniques in a dynamic panel analysis, which alleviates the possible positive bias in difference GMM due to the persistence of lagged dependent variables as instruments. We find strong evidence of a negative effect on growth from income inequality, which contradicts the findings of Forbes [2000, September. A reassessment of the relationship between inequality and growth, American Economic Review, 90(4), pp. 869–887] and Li and Zou [1998, October. Income inequality is not harmful for growth: Theory and evidence, Review of Development Economics, 2(3), pp. 318–34]. Further analyses using combined Gini coefficients show that the difference can be overall attributed to the problem of omitted control variables and the differences in how the variations in inequality across countries are reflected. We also find that the negative effects of inequality on economic growth can be of great significance when using a sample of less developed countries or more recent inequality data set. 相似文献
6.
7.
新古典经济增长模型预测,随着时间的推移,人均收入的差距将会缩小,收入不平等将会逐渐趋同。本文利用1995年—2012年新疆15个地州的空间面板数据,采用跨部门模型和空间面板数据模型,并考虑空间交互效应来检验上述预测对新疆的正确性。研究结果显示,在对教育程度、失业、产业构成、人均收入的空间滞后增长以及区域固定效应进行调控之后,人均收入存在条件收敛,而收入不平等则存在无条件收敛。 相似文献
8.
9.
中国的对外开放和收入差距 总被引:26,自引:0,他引:26
本文主要研究中国的对外开放对收入差距的影响。首先,根据传统的Heckscher-Ohlin模型以及Stolper-Samuelson定理,由于中国在劳动密集型的产品上具有比较优势,贸易开放有利于出口更多劳动密集型产品,进口更多资本和技术密集型产品,贸易的增加最终促使要素价格均等化,从而降低收入不平等的程度。其次,对外开放引入了大量的外商直接投资(FDI),外资企业支付的高工资使技术工人工资提高,从而扩大了收入差距。另一方面,如果中国进口更多资本和技术密集的产品,同时引入更多的外资,就会促进技术进步。本文先建立了简单的模型讨论“技术偏向性的技术进步”(skill-biased technological progress)对收入差距的影响,再考虑了发生在技术密集产业的中性的技术进步,在中国的实际劳动力市场特征下,这两种技术进步将会使技术工人(skilled worker)相对于非技术工人(unskilledworker)的工资上升,从而收入差距扩大。开放程度对收入差距的实际影响在理论界上历来是存在着广泛的争议,最终要取决于定量研究的结果。当作者将教育、失业率、中国经济转型过程中的发展战略等变量同时引入模型以后,实证分析结果显示中国的贸易开放倾向于扩大中国的个人之间的收入差距。 相似文献
10.
SUMMARYThe political authority of President Joko Widodo (Jokowi) was bolstered in the third quarter of 2015 by a cabinet reshuffle, his coalition's gaining a parliamentary majority, and several foreign-policy developments. Indonesia's request to rejoin OPEC, for example, after having left in 2008, seemed more about international relations than oil prices, while official visits to the Middle East and the United States allowed Jokowi to project his presidency on the international stage. He still faces resistance from within his own party, however.Jokowi's politically bold reshuffle of economic ministers in August soon yielded a range of policy announcements. In September and October, his government introduced its first substantial set of reforms—a number of economic policy packages intended, among other things, to attract investment and stimulate domestic demand. If even half of these policies are put in place, the impact on Indonesia's economy should be tangible.Few countries have escaped the effects of falling global commodity prices and China's growth slowdown. At 4.7%, year on year, in the third quarter Indonesia's rate of economic growth again fell short of the government's target. Slowing growth and a negative outlook have lowered market expectations and weakened the rupiah, which is also burdened by the large outstanding external debt held by corporate borrowers. Indonesia's real effective exchange rate has recently begun to depreciate, however, which may stimulate exports. Growth prospects will also improve if the substantial increase in capital and infrastructure spending allocated in the state budget is realised.Against this backdrop, we focus on what has happened to poverty and inequality in Indonesia since Jokowi took office. The distributional impacts of the current macroeconomic climate are likely to be hardest felt by the poor. Indonesia is well known for its record on poverty reduction, but between September 2014 and March 2015 the share of the population in poverty increased, even though economic growth was close to 5.0%. Slowing growth, rising food prices, the falling real wages of farmers, and the delayed disbursement of fuel-price compensation all had an effect. Such impacts may be mitigated in the medium term by Jokowi's budget reallocations to infrastructure, if realised, and his expansion of social spending. 相似文献
11.
Angus C. Chu 《Southern economic journal》2010,77(2):336-350
To analyze the effects of patent policy on growth and inequality, this article develops a quality‐ladder model with wealth heterogeneity and elastic labor supply. The model predicts that strengthening patent protection increases (a) economic growth by stimulating spending on research and development and (b) income inequality by raising the return on assets. Elastic labor supply creates an additional effect on income inequality. As for consumption inequality, the effect is ambiguous and depends on the elasticity of intertemporal substitution. Calibrating the model to the U.S. data shows that strengthening patent protection increases income inequality by more than consumption inequality, and this pattern is consistent with the data. 相似文献
12.
收入不平与未来增长负相关,但是在控制了产权保护与法治水平以后这一关系不再存在,说明真正影响经济增长的并不是表象上收入分配的平等程度,而是经济活动内在规则的公正与否。进一步的证据表明,收入不平等程度受到产权保护与法治水平的显著影响。良好的产权保护和法治是经济公正的集中体现,有利于减少寻租,缩小收入差距,促进经济增长,本文用理论模型和实证证据来说明这一点。 相似文献
13.
15.
Income Inequality and Kuznets' Hypothesis in Thailand 总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1
16.
本文利用投入产出和线性需求模型分析了碳税的价格影响、福利成本以及再分配效应。征税导致占中低收入居民支出比重较大的基本消费品价格大幅上涨,如电热水气、房屋、公共交通、食品等;从等价性变化、补偿性变化的角度看,城镇居民的福利损失随收入降低而上升,而农村居民中中等收入家庭损失最大;Atkinson公平指数显示碳税前后贫富差距有所扩大。因此,碳税具有一定累退性。但是,碳税边际福利成本及其收入差距影响并不大,因此政府可以通过转移支付手段缓解其负面冲击。 相似文献
17.
Long-Run Changes in British Income Inequality 总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1
LEE SOLTOW 《The Economic history review》1968,21(1):17-29
19.
20.