共查询到20条相似文献,搜索用时 15 毫秒
1.
Summary. We consider a linear exchange economy and its successive replicas. We study the notion of Cournot-Walras equilibrium in which
the consumers use the quantities of commodities put on the market as strategic variables. We prove that, generically, if the
number of replications is large enough but finite, the competitive behaviour is an oligopoly equilibrium. Then, under a mild
condition, which may be interpreted in terms of market regulation and/or market activity, we show that any sequence of oligopoly
equilibria of successive replica economies converges to the Walrasian outcome and furthermore that every oligopoly equilibrium
of large, but finite, replica is Pareto optimal. Consequently, under the same assumptions on the fundamentals of the economy,
one has an asymptotic result on the convergence of oligopoly equilibria to the Walras equilibrium together with a generic
existence result for the Cournot-Walras.
Received: June 20, 2002; revised version: November 20, 2002
RID="*"
ID="*" Part of this paper was written while the second author was visiting the Universidad de Vigo. The support of the department
of mathematics is gratefully acknowledged.
Correspondence to: J.M. Bonnisseau 相似文献
2.
Beth Allen 《Economic Theory》2003,21(2-3):527-544
Summary. This paper examines the ex ante core of a pure exchange economy with asymmetric information in which state-dependent allocations are required to satisfy
incentive compatibility. This restriction on players' strategies in the cooperative game can be interpreted as incomplete
contracts or partial commitment. An example is provided in which the incentive compatible core with nontransferable utility
is empty; the game fails to be balanced because convex combinations of incentive compatible net trades can violate incentive
compatibility. However, randomization of such strategies leads to ex post allocations which satisfy incentive compatibility and are feasible on average. Hence, convexity is preserved in such a model
and the resulting cooperative games are balanced. In this framework, an incentive compatible core concept is defined for NTU
games derived from economies with asymmetric information. The main result is nonemptiness of the incentive compatible core.
Received: December 26, 2001; revised version: June 11, 2002
RID="*"
ID"*" This work was financed, in part, by contract No 26 of the programme “P?le d'attraction interuniversitaire” of the Belgian
government, and, in part, by research grant SBR93-09854 from the U.S. National Science Foundation. Much of my thinking about
this topic was developed during a wonderful visit to CORE for the 1991–1992 academic year (on sabbatical from the University
of Pennsylvania). This paper was originally circulated in December 1991 as CARESS Working Paper #91-38, Center for Analytic
Research in Economics and the Social Sciences, Department of Economics, University of Pennsylvania and in February 1992 as
CORE Discussion Paper 9221, Center for Operations Research and Econometrics, Université Catholique de Louvain, Louvain-la-Neuve,
Belgium.
RID="*"
ID="*" At the very start of my research, Jean-Fran?ois Mertens was almost a co-author. Fran?ois Forges provided detailed comments
at a later stage, during my visit to THEMA, Université Cergy-Pontoise, in Spring 1997. They are entitled to the customary
disclaimer. 相似文献
3.
Summary. If the allocations of a differential information economy are defined as incentive compatible state-contingent lotteries over consumption goods, competitive equilibrium allocations exist and belong to the (ex ante incentive) core. Furthermore, any competitive equilibrium allocation can be viewed as an element of the core of the n-fold replicated economy, for every n. The converse holds under the further assumption of independent private values but not in general, as shown by a counter-example. Received: August 9, 1999; revised version: September 12, 1999 相似文献
4.
Long run equilibria in an asymmetric oligopoly 总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1
Yasuhito Tanaka 《Economic Theory》1999,14(3):705-715
Summary. Consider an oligopolistic industry composed of two groups (or populations) of firms, the low cost firms and the high cost
firms. The firms produce a homogeneous good. I study the finite population evolutionarily stable strategy defined by Schaffer
(1988), and the long run equilibrium in the stochastic evolutionary dynamics based on imitation and experimentation of strategies
by firms in each group. I will show the following results. 1) The finite population evolutionarily stable strategy (ESS) output
is equal to the competitive (or Walrasian) output in each group of the firms. 2) Under the assumption that the marginal cost
is increasing, the ESS state is the long run equilibrium in the stochastic evolutionary dynamics in the limit as the output
grid step, which will be defined in the paper, approaches to zero.
Received: September 19, 1997; revised: June 18, 1998 相似文献
5.
Gautam Bose 《Economic Theory》2003,22(2):457-467
Summary. An explanation is provided for the evolution of segmented marketplaces in a pairwise exchange economy. Large traders operating
in a pairwise exchange market prefer to meet other similar traders, because this enables them to trade their endowments in
a smaller number of encounters. Large and small traders, however, cannot be distinguished a priori, and the existence of the small traders imposes a negative externality on the large traders. We show that, under conditions
which are not very restrictive, establishing a separate market (perhaps with an entry fee) designated for the large traders
induces the two types of traders to segment themselves. However, this segmentation is not necessarily welfare improving.
Received: January 12, 2001; revised version: July 17, 2002
RID="*"
ID="*" I wish to thank the participants in the Friday Theory Workshop at the University of Sydney, and the participants at
the 17th Australian Theory Workshop at the University of Melbourne for comments and discussion. John Hillas and Stephen King
pointed out an omission in an earlier version, and Catherine de Fontenay and Hodaka Morita made extensive comments on earlier
drafts. This work was initiated while I was a short-term visitor at the University of Southern California. 相似文献
6.
Secret information acquisition in Cournot markets 总被引:2,自引:0,他引:2
Summary. Two-stage game models of information acquisition in stochastic oligopolies require the assumption that firms observe the
precision of information chosen by their competitors before determining quantities. This paper analyzes secret information
acquisition as a one-stage game. Relative to the two-stage game firms are shown to acquire less information. Policy implications
based on the two-stage game yield, therefore, too high taxes or too low subsidies for research activities. For the case of
heterogeneous duopoly we briefly discuss comparative statics results.
Received: August 9, 1999; revised version: May 31, 2000 相似文献
7.
This article develops a general model that estimates market power exertion in a bilateral market relationship for processors and retailers where each may also have market power in their primary input market and output markets, respectively. Monte Carlo experiments are used to generate industry data for market structures such as perfect competition, monopoly, monopsony, bilateral imperfect competition with an integrated processor/retailer, bilateral imperfect competition with separate processor and retailer, and bilateral imperfect competition with four adjacent upstream and downstream markets. Then, new empirical industrial organization models are estimated using the data with models that match the market structure under which the data were generated (true) and with models that reflect alternative market structures (alternative). The general model is derived using the production function approach without imposing the fixed proportion assumption. Monte Carlo simulation results indicate that the general model is preferred to alternative models that presume competitive behaviour by processors in primary input procurement and by retailers in the output market. Results indicate that less flexible models lead to biased market power estimates in the presence of market power in the corresponding input and output markets. 相似文献
8.
Konstantinos Serfes 《Economic Theory》2001,18(2):333-348
Summary. We study the process of learning in a differential information economy, with a continuum of states of nature that follow
a Markov process. The economy extends over an infinite number of periods and we assume that the agents behave non-myopically,
i.e., they discount the future. We adopt a new equilibrium concept, the non-myopic core. A realized agreement in each period
generates information that changes the underlying structure in the economy. The results we obtain serve as an extension to
the results in Koutsougeras and Yannelis (1999) in a setting where agents behave non-myopically. In particular, we examine
the following two questions: 1) If we have a sequence of allocations that are in an approximate non-myopic core (we allow
for bounded rationality), is it possible to find a subsequence that converges to a non-myopic core allocation in a limit full
information economy? 2) Given a non-myopic core allocation in a limit full information economy can we find a sequence of approximate
non-myopic core allocations that converges to that allocation?
Received: May 25, 1999; revised version: August 9, 1999 相似文献
9.
Rim Lahmandi-Ayed 《Economic Theory》2001,17(3):665-674
In a pure exchange economy, agents have the possibility of behaving strategically by putting only a part of their initial endowments on the market. An oligopoly equilibrium is defined to be a Nash equilibrium of the game in which agents choose simultaneously quantities to be put on the market. It is proved that under standard hypotheses, the oligopoly equilibrium leads to the competitive equilibrium when the economy is replicated an infinite number of times. Received: May 26, 1999; revised version: April 3, 2000 相似文献
10.
Summary. In a static exchange economy, when all the endowments are issued as securities on a stock exchange, Pareto optimal allocations may be reached by trading options on the market index (see Breeden and Litzenberger (1978)). We extend this result when some of the risks cannot be exchanged on the market. Options on an appropriate index, which typically differs from the market index, depending on the correlation of the non-tradable risks with the exchanged securities, are still an appropriate tool to support a (constrained) efficient equilibrium. This suggests that the recent development of derivatives based on interest rates may be an efficient way to reach a Pareto optimal allocation of risks. Received: June 16, 1997; revised version: July 25, 1997 相似文献
11.
Summary. We study pricing and product diffusion in a dynamic general equilibrium framework with product market frictions. Ongoing
R&D activity leads, with an endogenously determined probability, to continual improvements in product quality. We characterize
the steady-state equilibrium with endogenous product diffusion in which a number of different goods co-exist on the quality
ladder. We show that the severity of the economy's market frictions is a crucial determinant of the pricing structure, the
product diffusion pattern, the level of R&D investment, the rate of endogenous growth, the length of Schumpeterian product
cycles and the possibility of multiple growth paths. Eliminating market frictions leads to a degenerate product ladder of
precisely one step, containing only the most recent product, as in the monopolistic competition literature.
Received: August 16, 1999; revised version: March 6, 2001 相似文献
12.
Stefan Maus 《Economic Theory》2003,22(3):613-627
Summary. A condition is given that is equivalent to balancedness of all NTU-games derived from an exchange economy with asymmetric
information when endowments are variable. The condition is applicable to the ex-ante model with expected utilities, but also
to the more general model of Arrow-Radner type economies without subjective probabilities. Differences in the interpretation
of measurability assumptions between these two models are discussed, and another model with information consistent utility
functions is developed in which the result would also hold.
Received: December 12, 2001; revised version: November 1, 2002
RID="*"
ID="*"I thank two anonymous referees whose comments led to an improvement of the paper. 相似文献
13.
We consider an oligopolistic market game, in which the players are competing firms in the same market of a homogeneous consumption good. The consumer side is represented by a fixed demand function. The firms decide how much to produce of a perishable consumption good, and they decide upon a number of information signals to be sent into the population in order to attract customers. Due to the minimal information provided, the players do not have a well-specified model of their environment. Our main objective is to characterize the adaptive behavior of the players in such a situation. 相似文献
14.
Summary. A model that includes the cost of producing money is presented and the nature of the inefficient equilibria in the model
are examined. It is suggested that if one acknowledges that transactions are a form of production, which requires the consumption
of resources, then the concept of Pareto optimality is inappropriate for assessing efficiency. Instead it becomes necessary
to provide an appropriate comparative analysis of alternative transactions mechanisms in the appropriate context.
Received: September 5, 2000; revised version: May 3, 2001 相似文献
15.
Farhad Hüsseinov 《Economic Theory》2003,22(4):893-902
In this note two theorems strengthening Grodal's (1971) Theorem on correspondences are proved. The first drops the convexity
assumption. The second strengthens that theorem further for the case when the range is the positive orthant. In this case,
the conclusion of Grodal's Theorem - the intersection of the integral with the interior of the range being open- is modified
to read as the integral being a relative open subset of the positive orthant. An example is provided to show that, such a
strengthening is not valid in general. This allows us to dispense with the requirment of convexity of preferences in Grodal's
(1971) theorems on the closedness of the set of Pareto optimal allocations, the core, and the continuity of the core correspondence
for pure exchange economies. We apply this result to show that blocking coalitions in a large economy are stable.
Received: September 30, 1998; revised version: September 18, 2001
RID="*"
ID="*" The author is grateful to an anonymous referee for helpful comments. The usual disclaimer applies. 相似文献
16.
This paper examines endogenous merger formations in a mixed oligopoly. Applying the core as a solution concept, we analyze
which market structure(s) remain(s) stable when three firms—two symmetric private firms and one inefficient public firm—are
allowed to merge with each other in a mixed Cournot industry. We show that according to the value of the marginal cost of
the public firm, there always exists a pair of share ratios of the owners of both the (pre-merged) public firm and the (pre-merged)
private firm such that the market structure with the merger between the public firm and one private firm belongs to the core.
When the initial market structure is a mixed triopoly, it can only be blocked when one public firm and one private firm merge.
Furthermore, we conduct a similar analysis in a general mixed oligopoly with one public firm and n private firms.
相似文献
17.
Jingang Zhao 《Economic Theory》2001,18(3):635-648
Summary. This note provides two necessary and sufficient conditions for the relative interior of the core (and the base polyhedron) to be non-empty: (i) the second largest excess of the prenucleolus is negative; (ii) the grand coalition's payoff is greater than the minimum no-blocking payoff. Such conditions imply an intuitive method in proving core existence, they also imply results on the sensitivity of the base polyhedron and the core. Received: June 25, 1999; revised version: May 8, 2000 相似文献
18.
Summary. The paper analyzes the properties of cores with differential information, as economies converge to complete information.
Two core concepts are investigated: the private core, in which agents' net trades are measurable with respect to agents' private
information, and the incentive compatible core, in which coalitions of agents are restricted to incentive compatible allocations.
Received: March 15, 2000; revised version: August 24, 2000 相似文献
19.
Christopher Sleet 《Economic Theory》2001,17(2):371-397
Summary. This paper considers the existence and computation of Markov perfect equilibria in games with a “monotone” structure. Specifically, it provides a constructive proof of the existence of Markov perfect equilibria for a class of games in which a) there is a continuum of players, b) each player has the same per period payoff function and c) these per period payoff functions are supermodular in the player's current and past action and have increasing differences in the player's current action and the entire distribution of actions chosen by other players. The Markov perfect equilibria that are analyzed are symmetric, not in the sense that each player adopts the same action in any period, but rather in the sense that each player uses the same policy function. Since agents are typically distributed across many states they will typically take different actions. The formal environment considered has particular application to models of industries (or economies) in which firms face costs of price adjustment. It is in this context that the results are developed. Received: November 9, 1999; revised version: February 10, 2000 相似文献
20.
Sang-Seung Yi 《Economics Letters》1996,50(3):437-442
How does the sale of assets from a small firm to a large firm affect the equilibrium price in oligopoly? Using the ‘cross-sectional differentiation’ technique introduced by Farrell and Shapiro (Rand Journal of Economics, 1990, 21, 275–292), I show that the equilibrium price rises if the common production technology is homogeneous of degree t, 0<t1. 相似文献