共查询到20条相似文献,搜索用时 0 毫秒
1.
Fei Song 《Experimental Economics》2006,9(2):179-180
Using an experimental trust game, I examine whether the perspectives and behavior of group representatives and consensus groups
differ from those of the same individuals in an analogous inter-individual situation. A primary goal of this research is to
extend past work on trust and reciprocity by examining the impact of the social contexts within which social interactions
are characteristically embedded. Specifically, this research concerns whether norms and dynamics of trust and reciprocity
differ in the contexts of inter-individual and inter-group interactions. First, I examine whether dynamics of trust and reciprocity
differ in various inter-group interactions where inter-group decisions are operationalized as 1) autonomous group representatives,
i.e., individuals who are given the responsibility of unilaterally making a decision on behalf of a three-person group engaging
with a group representative of another such group; and 2) consensus groups, i.e., group members making a consensus trust or
reciprocity decision for their groups via a collective process with another such group. Results of these studies show that
1) people trust less and reciprocate less when responsible for a group or organizational decision as autonomous group representatives;
2) consensus groups do not differ from individuals in their level of trust but show dramatically less reciprocity. The group
consensus mechanism in fact produced by far the lowest reciprocity level, significantly lower than that exhibited by either
individuals or autonomous group representatives. Thus, inter-group trust and reciprocity dynamics are not readily inferable
from their inter-individual counterparts. Moreover, an important implication is emerging here: the extent and direction of
the discrepancy between individual and group choices in regard to trust and reciprocity levels and possibly other social preferences
in general may depend importantly on the precise details of the group decision-making mechanism, for example whether decisions
are made consensually, by majority vote, or by a group leader or representative. In addition to examining the level of trust
and reciprocity that occur in these various situations, I also studied, using both behavioral and questionnaire data, the
roles of self-interest, social influence, and group dynamics in trust and reciprocity perceptions and behavior. The results
showed that there exist discrepancies between behavioral forecasts and the actual behavior, and that trusting behavior is
driven strongly by expectation of level of reciprocation, while reciprocating behavior is driven strongly by the difference
between trust expectation and actual trust received. 相似文献
2.
3.
In their article in this issue of Ecological Economics, Kuosmanen and Kuosmanen [Kuosmanen, T. and Kuosmanen, N., this issue. How Not to Measure Sustainable Value (and How One Might). Ecological Economics.] aim to criticise the measurement of Sustainable Value as proposed in our previous research. By adopting a production perspective and based on a productive efficiency analysis, they claim that the proposed way of measuring Sustainable Value represents an invalid simplification that rests on restrictive and unrealistic assumptions. Our response is to show that their argument rests on a fundamental misspecification of the Sustainable Value approach. We identify three conceptual misfits: a mismatch in the perspective of the analysis, a misspecification of opportunity costs and the irrelevance of production functions. Ultimately, Kuosmanen and Kuosmanen's train of thought rests entirely within the realm of productive efficiency analysis, whereas Sustainable Value builds on the foundations of financial economics and consequently adopts a macro rather than a firm perspective. It is thus not surprising that the findings of Kuosmanen and Kuosmanen appear to contradict the Sustainable Value approach. However, this is due to their fundamental misspecification of the Sustainable Value approach. As a result, rather than providing novel insights into how Sustainable Value might be measured in a better way, they do not measure Sustainable Value at all. 相似文献
4.
We examine a growth model with consumption externalities where agents differ in their initial capital endowment and their reference group. We show under which conditions the aggregate equilibrium with heterogeneous agents replicates that obtained with a representative consumer, despite the fact that different individuals have different consumption levels. Next we consider the implications of the presence of consumption externalities for the long-run distributions of income and wealth. We find that, in a growing economy, “keeping up with the Joneses” results in less inequality than would prevail in an economy with no consumption externalities. 相似文献
5.
June Lapidus 《Feminist Economics》2013,19(2):227-236
Amidst increasing numbers of gays and lesbians having children, political opposition to gay marriage, and government efforts to discourage female-headed households by funding marriage initiatives, the author reflects on her life as a single lesbian mom. Following in the feminist tradition of using personal experiences as a starting point, the article looks at the social space between single heterosexual moms and lesbian mother couples. 相似文献
6.
Daniel John Zizzo 《International Review of Economics》2011,58(1):91-103
Sharing a common fate with some people but not others may affect how economic agents behave in economic transactions, quite
independently of strategic incentives. We present an experimental test of the effect of perceptions of common fate on the
inducement of economic discrimination in bilateral settings. In settings where the bargaining power was all with one subject
(the dictator game and a ‘unilateral power game’), about half of the subjects engaged in negative discrimination: insiders
were not treated better relative to control sessions, but outsiders were treated worse. Discrimination may be induced by a
more conflictual perception of the decision problem. 相似文献
7.
8.
In a multi-stage contest known as a two-player race, players display two fundamental behaviors: (1) the laggard will make a last stand in order to avoid the cost of losing; and (2) the player who is ahead will defend his lead if it is threatened. Last stand behavior, in particular, contrasts with previous research where the underdog simply gives up. The distinctive results are achieved by introducing losing penalties and discounting into the racing environment. This framework permits the momentum effect, typically ascribed to the winner of early stages, to be more thoroughly examined. I study the likelihood that the underdog will catch up. I find that neck-and-neck races are common when the losing penalty is large relative to the winning prize, while landslide victories occur when the prize is relatively large. Closed-form solutions are given for the case where players have a common winning prize and losing penalty. 相似文献
9.
Mark Gradstein 《European Journal of Political Economy》1998,14(4):575-585
This paper undertakes a comparative analysis of rent-seeking contests in terms of the amount and the timing of effort they elicit from the participants. The optimal contest structure—the one that maximizes the discounted sum of efforts—is found to hinge on the degree of impatience of the contest organizers, the more patient of whom prefer longer contests consisting of pairwise matches among the contestants. Heterogeneity of the contestants' quality also turns out to play an important role in the comparison. 相似文献
10.
The most promising candidates for estimating vector autoregressive models with long, stationary, possibly heterogeneous panel data sets (panel-VARs) are the fixed effect (FE) and the mean group (MG) estimators. With a view to providing guidance to applied researchers on how to pool in a panel-VAR, this paper compares the performance of the FE and the MG estimators both asymptotically and in Monte Carlo simulations. The main results of the analysis suggest the use of both estimators in applied work. If FE and MG estimates give similar estimates, the FE estimator should be used because it is more efficient. If they differ, the MG estimator should be used only if the panel is sufficiently long — say, twice as long as usually recommended in the dynamic panel data literature. If FE and MG estimates differ and the panel is not long enough, neither is generally a desirable alternative and other estimation techniques are needed. 相似文献
11.
The motto of Tongji University whose name literallymeans "we are all in the same boat must work to-gether to reach common goals" describes the harvest ofISEE leaders' mission to China in May . ISEE Presi-dent Joan Martinez-Alier President-Elect Peter May andthe society's founder first President Robert Costanzaas well as ISEE member Robert Ayres participated in aseries of events meetings in Shanghai Beijing witha view to build institutional collaboration.…… 《生态经济(英文版)》2007,3(3)
The motto of Tongji University, whose name literallymeans "we are all in the same boat, and must work to-gether to reach common goals", describes the harvest ofISEE leaders' mission to China in May 2007. ISEE Presi-dent Joan Martinez-Alier, President-Elect Peter May andthe society's founder and first President, Robert Costanzaas well as ISEE member Robert Ayres, participated in aseries of events and meetings in Shanghai and Beijing witha view to build institutional collaboration. 相似文献
12.
Pierre-Guillaume Méon 《Constitutional Political Economy》2006,17(3):207-216
This note studies the volatility of the policy chosen by a committee whose members’ preferences are volatile, due to common and individual preferences shocks. It is shown that majority voting mitigates the latter but not the former. The volatility of the policy is smaller the smaller the volatility of members’ preferences, smaller the larger the size of the committee, and smaller than if it was chosen by a single member. The results hold in a context of uncertainty and with multidimensional issues.
相似文献
Pierre-Guillaume MéonEmail: Phone: +32-2-650-66-48 |
13.
Abstract . Motivated by GATT, we endogenize the formation of a club whose members have to abide by the MFN principle of non-discrimination. The underlying model is that of oligopolistic intraindustry trade. While an MFN club does not alter average tariff levels across countries, it increases aggregate world welfare; makes non-members worse off; and can immiserize its high cost members. These results imply that (i) core WTO rules such as MFN are valuable even if multilateral negotiations deliver limited trade liberalization and (ii) the distributional effects of MFN maybe one reason why developing countries have been granted Special and Differential treatment at the WTO. 相似文献
14.
15.
This paper examines the impact of retirement on cognitive functioning by gender in urban China and investigates the underlying mechanisms. Based on data from the China Health and Retirement Longitudinal Study, the paper uses the mandatory retirement ages and different policy enforcement between the public and private sectors as instruments for retirement status. The analysis finds substantial gender heterogeneity in the effect of retirement on cognition, with a positive and significant effect for males, but a negative and less significant effect for females. The beneficial effects on cognition are stronger for male blue-collar workers, who are likely to pursue a more active lifestyle at retirement. Further investigation shows that the results are partly driven by differential behavioral changes at retirement, and the gender difference in retirement ages may also play a potential role. 相似文献
16.
Heidi J. Albers Carolyn Fischer James N. Sanchirico 《Resource and Energy Economics》2010,32(4):483-499
The spread of invasive species (IS) is an inherently spatial process, and management of invasive species occurs over spatially heterogeneous regions, but policy constraints can restrict management responses to be homogeneous across regions. Using a spatial bioeconomic model that includes a representation of invasive species ecology based on heterogeneous environments that are linked across space and time by human and ecological pathways, we compare optimal spatially heterogeneous policy to spatially uniform policy. We explore the magnitude and pattern of the policy differences with emphasis on the influence of different types of underlying heterogeneity across locations. 相似文献
17.
Repayment performance in group lending: Evidence from Jordan 总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1
Moh'd Al-Azzam 《Journal of development economics》2012,97(2):404-414
Using data from a survey of 160 urban borrowing groups of the Microfund for Women in Jordan, we investigate the effect of screening, peer monitoring, group pressure, and social ties on borrowing groups' repayment behavior as an indirect test of different theoretical models. The dependent variable used captures the intensity of default measured by the total number of days of late repayment after each due date, allowing us to use count data models with cluster standard errors. As theory predicts, our empirical analysis suggests that peer monitoring, group pressure, and social ties reduce delinquency. The paper uncovers interesting evidence about the role of social ties and religion. Most notably, in an area where religion contributes to attitudes and beliefs of individuals, we find that religiosity improves repayment performance. 相似文献
18.
Central Asia has low labor force participation rates for women, despite high levels of poverty in the non-oil producing countries. Female labor force participation is related to competing uses for women’s time, especially in a context of poor infrastructure and limited availability of purchased replacements for household labor. We examine factors affecting women’s participation in employment and reproductive household work in Tajikistan, drawing on the 2003 Tajikistan Living Standards Survey. We incorporate specific conditions in Central Asia, including the prevalence of extended family households, norms about how women share household work, an absence of market substitutes for caring and reproductive labor, employment in family enterprises and poor infrastructure, especially in rural areas. We estimate the system using a Generalized Maximum Entropy (GME) approach. We find that few individual and household characteristics are related to time in employment. Time in noncare reproductive work decreases if a woman receives direct remuneration for her employment (compared to working in a family farm or enterprise but receiving no direct remuneration), but increases if the woman has less access to infrastructure. Rural women spend more time in both employment and non-care reproductive work than urban women, but less time in care work. Lack of infrastructure may leave women with few choices with respect to non-care reproductive work, while overall levels of time poverty create pressures on care time. 相似文献
19.
This paper is aimed to provide some responses to the following three hotly debated issues regarding China’s new rural cooperative medical system (NCMS), which was launched at the beginning of 2003. Firstly, how many people would join the system voluntarily? Secondly, can the system be self-balanced? And thirdly, would the lump-sum tax benefit the rich more than the poor? We build a decision model with heterogeneous agents and we compute the implications of NCMS and find under certain conditions, the balanced-system can be sustained and the rate of participation could be higher than 90%. Moreover, it is the unhealthy poor that benefit more from NCMS. 相似文献
20.
Ian I. Mitroff Harold Quinton Distinguished Professor of Business Policy 《Technological Forecasting and Social Change》1985,28(1):3-12
It is by now a commonplace to say that today the world is in the midst of a revolution as profound as any we have ever experienced. It is, however, much less of a commonplace to specify precisely of what this revolution consists. The contention of this article is that the revolution is more than a mere shift in our industrial or technological base. Fundamentally, it is a change in underlying mental attitudes—how we conceive of the world. It is thus a shift in our values but at the same time much more basic than this alone.This article describes the nature of the change that is occuring in mental attitudes. However, it does not do so in a traditional way. Primarily, it does it by means of a fable. The reason is that the shift we are experiencing is also in part a shift in our aesthetic vision, that is, in the styles of discourse that we use to describe reality. In short, different conceptions of the world require different stylistic forms. The full nuances of a new era can not be captured by the forms of the past. 相似文献