首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
相似文献
 共查询到20条相似文献,搜索用时 15 毫秒
1.
Knowing that a decision maker maximizes expected utility with respect to some (unknown) utility U and some (unknown) probability P, what can one tell about P by observing his decisions? We discuss this revealed preference question primarily in the simple case of a two-element (H and T) state space, and show that the possible revelations of PT/PH are precisely those of the form PT/PHε∪Kk=1kk), for some algebraic numbers γkk.  相似文献   

2.
We discuss estimation of the model Yi=XibY+eYi, Ti=XibT+ eTi, when data on the continuous dependent variable Y and on the independent variables X are observed iff the ‘truncation variable’ T>0 and when T is latent. This case is distinct from both (i) the‘censored sample’ case, in which Y data are available iff T>0, T is latent and X data are available for all observations, and (ii) the ‘observed truncation variable’ case, in which both Y and X are observed iff T>0 and in which the actual value of T is observed whenever T>0. We derive a maximum-likelihood procedure for estimating this model and discuss identification and estimation.  相似文献   

3.
Dr. Th. Pfaff 《Metrika》1983,30(1):125-138
SequencesT (n) ,n∈N, are considered, whereT (n) estimates a vector parameter ?∈R p from an i.i.d. sample of sizen, and such sequences are compared on the basis of their risks ∫L(n 1/2(T n (x)?θ))P θ n (dx) relative to loss functionsL:R p →R. A characterization is given for sequencesT *(n) ,n∈N, which generate an essentially complete class in the following sense: For any sequenceT (n) ,n∈N, there exist functions Φ n ,n∈N, such that forn→∞ we have $$\begin{gathered} \smallint L (n^{1/2} (T^{*(n)} + n^{ - 1} \Phi _n (T^{*(n)} ) - \theta )) dP_\theta ^n \leqslant \hfill \\ \leqslant \smallint L (n^{1/2} (T^{(n)} - \theta )) dP_\theta ^n + o (n^{ - 1} ), \hfill \\ \end{gathered} $$ for every ? and everyL satisfying certain conditions. If the estimator-sequences are compared by their risks ∫W(T (n) d P θ n ,θ) with respect to loss functionsW:R p ×Θ→R then a similar result on asymptotically complete classes is valid. The results are obtained under the assumption thatT *(n) ,n∈N, andT (n) ,n∈N, admit stochastic expansions which are sufficiently regular, that the loss functionsL andW are sufficiently smooth and bounded by polynomials, and that the estimator-sequences have asymptotically bounded moments; the latter condition is not needed for bounded functionsL andW.  相似文献   

4.
Si mostra che, sotto condizioni di regolarità, seo è un’operazione associativa tra variabili casuali reali e indipendenti, è definibile una trasformata integrale ξ delle loro funzioni di ripartizione con la proprietà: ξx 0 Y (t)=ξx(t)·ξ y (t). Si indicano alcune proprietà di tale trasformata e si tratta della possibilità di estendere a un’operazione associativa risultati noti per l’addizione tra variabili casuali. In particolare ci si occupa dell’« infinita divisibilità » fornendo condizioni perché una variabile casualeX ammetta la rappresentazioneX=X 1O X 2O o X n per ognin naturale con leX i indipendenti e identicamente ditribuite.  相似文献   

5.
Let a1,…,an be a finite sequence of n real numbers. A subset {i1,…,ir} of the set {1,…,n } is called a balancing subset for a1,…,an if ai1 + … + air = 0. We discuss in this paper the maximum number of balancing subsets for given n.  相似文献   

6.
Given an arbitrary function x: RlRl satisfying Walras law and homogeneity, Debreu decomposed x into the sum of l ‘individually rational’ functions x(p)=Σlk=1[uvbar|x]k(p). Here we find explicit utility functions uk, constructed on the basis of a simple geometric intuition, which give rise to Debreu's excess demands [uvbar|x]k(p).  相似文献   

7.
In this note, it is argued that cointegration augments the distance between the differenced series. If two series, x t and y t , are integrated of order one and cointegrated and v t and w t are integrated of order one but not cointegrated then, under certain conditions, the distance between ??x t and ??y t is more than the distance between ??v t and ??w t .  相似文献   

8.
It is shown that, under certain conditions on a preference relation on a subset X of Rm, there exist real-valued functions u and v on X such that x is preferred to y if and only if u(x)>v(y). This generalises the familiar representation of preferences by a utility function in the case where the preference and indifference relations are transitive. The continuity of the functions u and v is also discussed.  相似文献   

9.
Let G = (N,W) be a strong weighted majority game and let A be a set of alternatives. Denote by L the set of linear orders on A. A social choice function F:LNA is a representation of G if the simple game G1(F) associated with F equals G. A coalition S is determining in G if it satisfies the following condition. Let F be a representation of G and let RN ? LN. Then, if a simple majority of the members of S consider an alternative x to be their best choice, then S can ‘enforce’ x to be a Nash equilibrium payoff in the resulting non-cooperative voting game g(F,RN). In this paper we generalize the above notion of a determining coalition to committees (i.e., proper and monotonic simple games), and give a complete characterization of the set of determining coalitions of a committee. Furthermore, we discuss our notion of a determining coalition in the light of some real-life data on formation of coalitions in town councils in Israel.  相似文献   

10.
To estimate α in the model yt = ut+αut?1, we consider a proposal by Durbin (Biometrika, 1969). It consists in fitting an autoregression of order k to the data, and deriving from there an estimate α^. The probability limit and the variance of the limiting normal distribution of α^ are presented and discussed in detail, when the sample size T → ∞, but k remains fixed. The differences between the resulting values and those corresponding to the maximum likelihood estimator are exponentially decreasing functions of k. Several modifications of the estimator are discussed and found consistent, but asymptotically inefficient.  相似文献   

11.
LetX 1,X 2, …,X n(n ? 2) be a random sample on a random variablex with a continuous distribution functionF which is strictly increasing over (a, b), ?∞ ?a <b ? ∞, the support ofF andX 1:n ?X 2:n ? … ?X n:n the corresponding order statistics. Letg be a nonconstant continuous function over (a, b) with finiteg(a +) andE {g(X)}. Then for some positive integers, 1 <s ?n $$E\left\{ {\frac{1}{{s - 1}}\sum\limits_{i - 1}^{s - 1} {g(X_{i:n} )|X_{s:n} } = x} \right\} = 1/2(g(x) + g(a^ + )), \forall x \in (a,b)$$ iffg is bounded, monotonic and \(F(x) = \frac{{g(x) - g(a^ + )}}{{g(b^ - ) - g(a^ + )}},\forall x \in (a,b)\) . This leads to characterization of several distribution functions. A general form of this result is also stated.  相似文献   

12.
Suppose V and U are two independent mean zero random variables, where V has an asymmetric distribution with two mass points and U has some zero odd moments (having a symmetric distribution suffices). We show that the distributions of V and U are nonparametrically identified just from observing the sum V+U, and provide a pointwise rate root n estimator. This can permit point identification of average treatment effects when the econometrician does not observe who was treated. We extend our results to include covariates X, showing that we can nonparametrically identify and estimate cross section regression models of the form Y=g(X,D)+U, where D is an unobserved binary regressor.  相似文献   

13.
This paper concerns the existence of utility representations for preferences defined on a path connected space X. This includes any convex set. A classical result of Eilenberg (1941) proves the existence of utility representations when the consumption set is connected and separable. In an infinite dimensional space the above result may not be useful, because we lack, in general, the separability of the space. The non-separable spaces L and ca(K) are typical examples in mathematical economics. In this paper we show that a continuous preference relation ≽, on X has a continuous utility representation if and only if it is countably bounded, i.e., there is some countable subset F of X such that for all x in X there exist y and z in F with yxz. An easy corollary states that any continuous preference which has a best and a worst point has a continuous representation. We also obtain a convex continuous preference on a Banach lattice that has not a utility representation, because it is not countably bounded.  相似文献   

14.
Daniel Rost 《Metrika》1997,45(1):39-51
Letη n ,n ∈ ?, be arbitrary functions defined on a probability space (ω,A,P) with values in a normed vector spaceB 1 ,μ ∈ B 1 andξ 0 a separable random element inB 1 such thatξ n :=√n(η n ) converges weakly toξ 0 in the sense of Hoffmann-Jørgensen. Then with (B 2, ∥·∥2) being another normed vector space andφ:B 1B 2 compactly differentiable atμ with derivateD μ, the random variable $\parallel \sqrt n (\phi (n_n ) - \phi (\mu )) - D_\mu (\sqrt n (n_n - \mu ))\parallel 2*$ converges to 0P-stochastically where “*” denotes the measurable cover. We show that the classicalδ — method extends to the non-measurable case where in the proof we shall not make use of any representation theorems but only of a slight refinement of the usual characterisation of compact differentiability, due to the fact that we will not assume {ξ n :n ∈ ?} being tight.  相似文献   

15.
Suits' model of the watermelon market is reformulated as a disequilibrium model and the likelihood function is derived under various assumptions concerning the amount of available information. Such models are characterized by a min condition as in yt = min(Dt, St) for an ordinary demand-supply model, where the observed quantity yt is the smaller demand and supply. Varying amounts of information may be available depending on which variables are observed and on whether prior information is available for separating the sample into subsets for which Dt < St and conversely. The likelihood function corresponding to the least amount of prior information is shown to be unbounded without a certain variance ratio restriction. Computations are successfully carried out both with the original model and Monte Carlo experiments and the effect of different amounts of information on MSE's is analyzed.  相似文献   

16.
In this paper we say that a preference (i.e. irreflexive) relationP isregular (or aweak order) if both it and its non-comparability relation are transitive; we also say that a preference relationP * is aconvex extension of another preference relationP ifP?P * holds andP * is regular and convex-valued. We prove that a convex extension ofP exists if and only if every non-empty and finite set of alternativesA is not included in the convex hull of ∪ xA P(x).  相似文献   

17.
Stein-Rule estimator for regression problems has been studied by several authors including Sclove (1968) and others listed in Vinod's (1978) survey. Ullah and Ullah (1978) provide the expressions for the mean squared error (MSE) of a double k-class (KK) estimator with parameters k1 and k2. When k2=1 the Stein-Rule estimator becomes a special case of KK and an optimal choice of k1 is known. This paper explores optimal theoretical choice of k1 and k2. We note that negative choices of k2 are permissible, and that thereis a large range of choices for K1 and k2 where the MSE of the Stein-Rule estimator can be reduced for regression problems based on multicollinear data. A simulation experiment is included.  相似文献   

18.
We consider the mixed AR(1) time series model $$X_t=\left\{\begin{array}{ll}\alpha X_{t-1}+ \xi_t \quad {\rm w.p.} \qquad \frac{\alpha^p}{\alpha^p-\beta ^p},\\ \beta X_{t-1} + \xi_{t} \quad {\rm w.p.} \quad -\frac{\beta^p}{\alpha^p-\beta ^p} \end{array}\right.$$ for ?1 < β p ≤ 0 ≤ α p  < 1 and α p ? β p  > 0 when X t has the two-parameter beta distribution B2(p, q) with parameters q > 1 and ${p \in \mathcal P(u,v)}$ , where $$\mathcal P(u,v) = \left\{u/v : u < v,\,u,v\,{\rm odd\,positive\,integers} \right\}.$$ Special attention is given to the case p = 1. Using Laplace transform and suitable approximation procedures, we prove that the distribution of innovation sequence for p = 1 can be approximated by the uniform discrete distribution and that for ${p \in \mathcal P(u,v)}$ can be approximated by a continuous distribution. We also consider estimation issues of the model.  相似文献   

19.
In credibility theory, an unobservable random vector Y is approximated by a random vector ? in a pre-assigned set A of admitted estimators for Y. The credibility approximation ? for Y is best in the sense that it is the vector V ? A minimizing the distance between V and Y. The credibility estimator depends on observable random variables but also on unknown structure parameters. In the practical models, the latter can be estimated from realizations of the observable random variables.  相似文献   

20.
Unlike other popular measures of income inequality, the Gini coefficient is not decomposable, i.e., the coefficient G(X) of a composite population X=X1∪…∪Xr cannot be computed in terms of the sizes, mean incomes and Gini coefficients of the components Xi. In this paper upper and lower bounds (best possible for r=2) for G(X) in terms of these data are given. For example, G(X1∪…∪Xr)≧ΣαiG(Xi), where αi is the proportion of the pop ulation in Xi. One of the tools used, which may be of interest for other applications, is a lower bound for ∫0f(x)g(x)dx (converse to Cauchy's inequality) for monotone decreasing functions f and g.  相似文献   

设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号