首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
相似文献
 共查询到20条相似文献,搜索用时 250 毫秒
1.
Necessary and sufficient conditions are given for the existence of two continuous real valued functions u and v on a connected topological space X endowed with a preference relation ≺ (i.e., an asymmetric binary relation) such that y is preferred to x if and only if v(y)>u(x). It is shown that these conditions - a slight generalization of the usual ones encountered in classical utility theory - entail the existence of such a continuous representation u, v with u and v continuous utility functions for two complete preorders intimately connected with the preference relation ≺.  相似文献   

2.
This paper concerns the existence of utility representations for preferences defined on a path connected space X. This includes any convex set. A classical result of Eilenberg (1941) proves the existence of utility representations when the consumption set is connected and separable. In an infinite dimensional space the above result may not be useful, because we lack, in general, the separability of the space. The non-separable spaces L and ca(K) are typical examples in mathematical economics. In this paper we show that a continuous preference relation ≽, on X has a continuous utility representation if and only if it is countably bounded, i.e., there is some countable subset F of X such that for all x in X there exist y and z in F with yxz. An easy corollary states that any continuous preference which has a best and a worst point has a continuous representation. We also obtain a convex continuous preference on a Banach lattice that has not a utility representation, because it is not countably bounded.  相似文献   

3.
In the usual linear model y = +u, the error vector u is not observable and the vector r of least squares residuals has a singular covariance matrix that depends on the design matrix X. We approximate u by a vectorr1 = G(JA'y+Kz) of uncorrelated ‘residuals’, where G and (J, K) are orthogonal matrices, A'X = 0 and A'A = I, while z is either 0 or a random vector uncorrelated with u satisfying E(z) = E(J'u) = 0, V(z) = V(J'u) = σ2I. We prove that r1-r is uncorrelated with r-u, for any such r1, extending the results of Neudecker (1969). Building on results of Hildreth (1971) and Tiao and Guttman (1967), we show that the BAUS residual vector rh = r+P1z, where P1 is an orthonormal basis for X, minimizes each characteristic root of V(r1-u), while the vector rb of Theil's BLUS residuals minimizes each characteristic root of V(Jra-r), cf. Grossman and Styan (1972). We find that tr V(rh-u) < tr V(Jrb-u) if and only if the average of the singular values of P1K is less than 12, and give examples to show that BAUS is often better than BLUS in this sense.  相似文献   

4.
This paper considers the disturbance specification ε = v ? u of the stochastic frontier model. For v distributed zero-mean normal and u half normal or exponential, we evaluate the population correlation coefficients between u and three estimators of u, E(u|ε) and two linear estimators, for various values of the signal-to-noise ratio.  相似文献   

5.
In this paper we say that a preference (i.e. irreflexive) relationP isregular (or aweak order) if both it and its non-comparability relation are transitive; we also say that a preference relationP * is aconvex extension of another preference relationP ifP?P * holds andP * is regular and convex-valued. We prove that a convex extension ofP exists if and only if every non-empty and finite set of alternativesA is not included in the convex hull of ∪ xA P(x).  相似文献   

6.
Given X,, where X is a topologically connected space and is an asymmetric binary relation, necessary and sufficient conditions are presented for the existence of a continuous representation of the form, u, δ; that is, for x,yX, xy if and only if u(x)>u(y)+δ where u:X→ is continuous and δ is a strictly positive real number. The results are related to existing results for numerical representations of interval orders and semiorders.  相似文献   

7.
This paper describes properties of homothetic preferences on a subset X of a vector space which is star-shaped with respect to 0 (e.g., a cone). We prove that a preference relation on X is homothetic, greedy and calibrated if and only if there exists a positively homogeneous function that represents it. This function is unique up to a strictly increasing and positively homogeneous transformation. As a corollary, we find that, if X is contained in a topological vector space, then œ is homothetic and continuous if and only if there exists a positively homogeneous and continuous function that represents it.  相似文献   

8.
9.
It is shown that if (X 1, X 2, . . . , X n ) is a random vector with a logconcave (logconvex) joint reliability function, then X P = min iP X i has increasing (decreasing) hazard rate. Analogously, it is shown that if (X 1, X 2, . . . , X n ) has a logconcave (logconvex) joint distribution function, then X P  = max iP X i has decreasing (increasing) reversed hazard rate. If the random vector is absolutely continuous with a logconcave density function, then it has a logconcave reliability and distribution functions and hence we obtain a result given by Hu and Li (Metrika 65:325–330, 2007). It is also shown that if (X 1, X 2, . . . , X n ) has an exchangeable logconcave density function then both X P and X P have increasing likelihood ratio.  相似文献   

10.
In this paper, we focus our attention on the representability of a preference relation by differentiable utility functions when the consumption sets belong to an infinite dimensional commodity space. We obtain sufficient conditions for the existence of a Cr function representing a preference relation defined on an open subset of a Banach lattice.  相似文献   

11.
LetX 1,X 2, …,X n(n ? 2) be a random sample on a random variablex with a continuous distribution functionF which is strictly increasing over (a, b), ?∞ ?a <b ? ∞, the support ofF andX 1:n ?X 2:n ? … ?X n:n the corresponding order statistics. Letg be a nonconstant continuous function over (a, b) with finiteg(a +) andE {g(X)}. Then for some positive integers, 1 <s ?n $$E\left\{ {\frac{1}{{s - 1}}\sum\limits_{i - 1}^{s - 1} {g(X_{i:n} )|X_{s:n} } = x} \right\} = 1/2(g(x) + g(a^ + )), \forall x \in (a,b)$$ iffg is bounded, monotonic and \(F(x) = \frac{{g(x) - g(a^ + )}}{{g(b^ - ) - g(a^ + )}},\forall x \in (a,b)\) . This leads to characterization of several distribution functions. A general form of this result is also stated.  相似文献   

12.
The behavioral justification for public pensions: a survey   总被引:1,自引:1,他引:0  
Unfunded public pension systems are primarily justified on grounds that many individuals lack sufficient capacity to appropriately save for retirement. We begin with a review of the known principle that a standard life-cycle/permanent-income consumer who discounts the future at an exponential rate can benefit from an unfunded public pension system only if the internal rate of return exceeds the private rate of return. However, a pay-as-you-go program with a below market internal rate can in fact improve lifetime utility if the consumer misestimates social security benefits, uses a hyperbolic discount function rather than the exponential function, uses a short planning horizon, behaves impulsively, or if a fraction of the population do no saving at all. A literature has consequently arisen to study how severe these behavioral defects need to be in order to justify a pay-as-you-go program. We survey this literature, and we conclude that the results are highly mixed as to whether an unfunded public pension that earns a below-market internal rate of return can be justified on grounds of shortsightedness in model economies. The challenge for this literature is that the conclusions crucially depend on the particular values of the preference parameters that are used in the simulation experiments, and these preference parameters are not observable, nor is there much consensus concerning the values that should be used in simulations. In fact, even when the analysis is confined to a small and reasonable space of the unobservable preference parameters, it is possible to reach nearly any policy conclusion. We offer some guidance for future work in this area.
T. Scott FindleyEmail:
  相似文献   

13.
Unlike other popular measures of income inequality, the Gini coefficient is not decomposable, i.e., the coefficient G(X) of a composite population X=X1∪…∪Xr cannot be computed in terms of the sizes, mean incomes and Gini coefficients of the components Xi. In this paper upper and lower bounds (best possible for r=2) for G(X) in terms of these data are given. For example, G(X1∪…∪Xr)≧ΣαiG(Xi), where αi is the proportion of the pop ulation in Xi. One of the tools used, which may be of interest for other applications, is a lower bound for ∫0f(x)g(x)dx (converse to Cauchy's inequality) for monotone decreasing functions f and g.  相似文献   

14.
Let be an interval order on a topological space (X, τ), and let x ˜* y if and only if [y z x z], and x ˜** y if and only if [z x z y]. Then ˜* and ˜** are complete preorders. In the particular case when is a semiorder, let x ˜0 y if and only if x ˜* y and x ˜** y. Then ˜0 is a complete preorder, too. We present sufficient conditions for the existence of continuous utility functions representing ˜*, ˜** and ˜0, by using the notion of strong separability of a preference relation, which was introduced by Chateauneuf (Journal of Mathematical Economics, 1987, 16, 139–146). Finally, we discuss the existence of a pair of continuous functions u, υ representing a strongly separable interval order on a measurable topological space (X, τ, μ, ).  相似文献   

15.
We propose estimators of features of the distribution of an unobserved random variable W. What is observed is a sample of Y,V,X where a binary Y equals one when W exceeds a threshold V determined by experimental design, and X are covariates. Potential applications include bioassay and destructive duration analysis. Our empirical application is referendum contingent valuation in resource economics, where one is interested in features of the distribution of values W (willingness to pay) placed by consumers on a public good such as endangered species. Sample consumers with characteristics X are asked whether they favor (with Y=1 if yes and zero otherwise) a referendum that would provide the good at a cost V specified by experimental design. This paper provides estimators for quantiles and conditional on X moments of W under both nonparametric and semiparametric specifications.  相似文献   

16.
We consider a stochastic frontier model with error ε=v−uε=vu, where vv is normal and uu is half normal. We derive the distribution of the usual estimate of u,E(u|ε)u,E(u|ε). We show that as the variance of vv approaches zero, E(u|ε)−uE(u|ε)u converges to zero, while as the variance of vv approaches infinity, E(u|ε)E(u|ε) converges to E(u)E(u). We graph the density of E(u|ε)E(u|ε) for intermediate cases. To show that E(u|ε)E(u|ε) is a shrinkage of u towards its mean, we derive and graph the distribution of E(u|ε)E(u|ε) conditional on uu. We also consider the distribution of estimated inefficiency in the fixed-effects panel data setting.  相似文献   

17.
In the first part of the paper, we study concepts of supremum and maximum as subsets of a topological space XX endowed by preference relations. Several rather general existence theorems are obtained for the case where the preferences are defined by countable semicontinuous multi-utility representations. In the second part of the paper, we consider partial orders and preference relations “lifted” from a metric separable space XX endowed by a random preference relation to the space L0(X)L0(X) of XX-valued random variables. We provide an example of application of the notion of essential maximum to the problem of the minimal portfolio super-replicating an American-type contingent claim under transaction costs.  相似文献   

18.
Conditions are given for the existence of a pair of continuous real valued functions (u, v) representing an interval order on a topological space (X, ), in the sense that [xy if and only ifu(x)].I am deeply indepted to Professor Alain Chateauneuf for many valuable suggestions.  相似文献   

19.
Two random variables X and Y on a common probability space are mutually completely dependent (m.c.d.) if each one is a function of the other with probability one. For continuous X and Y, a natural approach to constructing a measure of dependence is via the distance between the copula of X and Y and the independence copula. We show that this approach depends crucially on the choice of the distance function. For example, the L p -distances, suggested by Schweizer and Wolff, cannot generate a measure of (mutual complete) dependence, since every copula is the uniform limit of copulas linking m.c.d. variables. Instead, we propose to use a modified Sobolev norm, with respect to which mutual complete dependence cannot approximate any other kind of dependence. This Sobolev norm yields the first nonparametric measure of dependence which, among other things, captures precisely the two extremes of dependence, i.e., it equals 0 if and only if X and Y are independent, and 1 if and only if X and Y are m.c.d. Examples are given to illustrate the difference to the Schweizer–Wolff measure.  相似文献   

20.
Given an arbitrary function x: RlRl satisfying Walras law and homogeneity, Debreu decomposed x into the sum of l ‘individually rational’ functions x(p)=Σlk=1[uvbar|x]k(p). Here we find explicit utility functions uk, constructed on the basis of a simple geometric intuition, which give rise to Debreu's excess demands [uvbar|x]k(p).  相似文献   

设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号