共查询到20条相似文献,搜索用时 15 毫秒
1.
Nigar Hashimzade 《Economic Theory》2003,21(4):907-912
Summary. In this paper I analyze the general equilibrium in a random Walrasian economy. Dependence among agents is introduced in the
form of dependency neighborhoods. Under the uncertainty, an agent may fail to survive due to a meager endowment in a particular
state (direct effect), as well as due to unfavorable equilibrium price system at which the value of the endowment falls short
of the minimum needed for survival (indirect terms-of-trade effect). To illustrate the main result I compute the stochastic
limit of equilibrium price and probability of survival of an agent in a large Cobb-Douglas economy.
Received June 7, 2001; revised version: January 7, 2002
RID="*"
ID="*" I would like to thank Mukul Majumdar and Thomas DiCiccio for helpful discussion and an anonymous referee for valuable
comments and suggestions. 相似文献
2.
Summary. This paper presents a model of a Walrasian exchange economy in which the preferences and endowments of the agents are random.
Stochastic interaction among the agents is formally described in terms of dependency neighborhoods. The main result is a characterization
of the distribution of market-clearing prices in a large economy.
Received: April 23, 1999; revised version: May 6, 1999 相似文献
3.
Summary. We study the implications of random discount rates of future generations for saving behavior and capital holdings in a steady
state competitive equilibrium with heterogeneous population. A well-known difficulty in deterministic economies with heterogeneous
households is that in steady state only the most patient households hold capital. In this paper we state conditions under
which this random discounting is sufficient for households other than the most patient ones to save. We thus provide a simple
and natural way of overcoming the aforementioned difficulty.
Received: December 28, 1998; revised version: May 19, 1999 相似文献
4.
A simple example of complex dynamics 总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1
Anjan Mukherji 《Economic Theory》1999,14(3):741-749
Summary. A discrete tatonnement process is analysed within the context of a two-person, two-good exchange economy where each person
has a Cobb-Douglas utility function. This process is shown to exhibit period doubling bifurcation, topological and ergodic
chaos.
Received: June 22, 1998; revised version: July 15, 1998 相似文献
5.
Takashi Kamihigashi 《Economic Theory》2000,15(2):463-468
Summary. Ekeland and Scheinkman (1986) prove the necessity of a standard transversality condition under certain technical conditions.
Their result is one of the most powerful on the necessity of a transversality condition currently available in the literature,
and their proof involves numerous estimations and relies on Ekeland's variational principle and Fatou's lemma. This note relaxes
some of their assumptions and provides a simple proof that uses neither Ekeland's principle nor a convergence result like
Fatou's lemma.
Received: April 24, 1998; revised version: September 8, 1998 相似文献
6.
Boiteux's solution to the shifting-peak problem and the equilibrium price density in continuous time
Summary. Bewley's condition on production sets, imposed to ensure the existence of an equilibrium price density when is the commodity space, is weakened to allow applications to continuous-time problems, and especially to peak-load pricing
when the users' utility and production functions are Mackey continuous. A general form for production sets with the required
property is identified, and examples are given of technologies which meet the weakened but not the original condition: these
include industrial use and storage of cyclically priced goods. This gives a framework for settling Boiteux's conjecture on
the shifting-peak problem. To make clear the restriction implicit in Mackey continuity, we interpret it as interruptibility
of demand; and we point out that, without this assumption, the equilibrium can feature pointed peaks with singular, instantaneous
capacity charges. The general equilibrium results are supplemented by results for prices supporting individual consumer or
producer optima.
Received: February 16, 2000; revised version: July 7, 2001 相似文献
7.
Summary. A service is produced for a set of agents. The service is binary, each agent either receives service or not, and the total
cost of service is a submodular function of the set receiving service. We investigate strategyproof mechanisms that elicit
individual willingness to pay, decide who is served, and then share the cost among them. If such a mechanism is budget balanced
(covers cost exactly), it cannot be efficient (serve the surplus maximizing set of users) and vice-versa. We characterize
the rich family of budget balanced and group strategyproof mechanisms and find that the mechanism associated with the Shapley
value cost sharing formula is characterized by the property that its worst welfare loss is minimal. When we require efficiency
rather than budget balance – the more common route in the literature – we find that there is a single Clarke-Groves mechanism
that satisfies certain reasonable conditions: we call this the marginal cost pricing mechanism. We compare the size of the
marginal cost pricing mechanism's worst budget surplus with the worst welfare loss of the Shapley value mechanism.
Received: October 26, 1998; revised version: December 3, 1999 相似文献
8.
Koji Shimomura 《Economic Theory》1999,14(2):501-503
Summary. Based on some elementary results on duality, the paper proposes a much simpler way of deriving the class of non-homothetic
CES production functions which was derived as a solution to a partial differential equation that defines the elasticity of
substitution.
Received: February 11, 1998; revised version: April 28, 1998 相似文献
9.
Ilaria Ossella 《Economic Theory》1999,14(3):597-607
Summary. This paper establishes a ‘turnpike theorem’ for a closed linear model of production with a primitive input requirement matrix.
Optimal programs of resource allocation have a ‘turnpike property’ if the growth factor of every sector in the economy converges,
in the long run, to a common value. The usefulness of such a theorem is due to the fact that the input requirement matrix
for an economy with a large number of goods may be primitive (some power of the matrix is strictly positive).
Received: April 19, 1998; revised version: July 15, 1998 相似文献
10.
>P>Summary. We provide a set of simple and intuitive set of axioms that allow for a direct and constructive proof of the Choquet Expected
Utility representation for decision making under uncertainty.
Received: October 29, 2002; revised version: November 13, 2002
RID="*"
ID="*" We thank Matthew Ryan for very useful comments and suggestions on related work and for encouraging us to write this
note.
Correspondence to: S. Grant 相似文献
11.
Summary. We analyze a model of coalitional bidding in which coalitions form endogenously and compete with each other. Since the nature
of this competition influences the way in which agents organize themselves into coalitions, our main aim is to characterize
the equilibrium coalition structure and the resulting bids. We do so in a simple model in which the seller may have good reason
to allow joint bidding. In particular, we study a model in which the agents are budget constrained, and are allowed to form
coalitions to pool their finances before engaging in the first price auction. We show that if the budget constraint is very
severe, the equilibrium coalition structure consists of two coalitions, one slightly larger than the other; interestingly,
it is not the grand coalition. This equilibrium coalition structure is one which yields (approximately) the maximum expected
revenue. Thus the seller can induce the optimal (revenue maximizing) degree of cooperation among budget constrained buyers
simply by permitting them to collude.
Received: June 25, 1999; revised version: November 13, 2000 相似文献
12.
Summary. Under take-it-or-leave-it offers, dynamic equilibria in the discrete time random matching model of money are a “translation”
of dynamic equilibria in the standard overlapping generations model. This formalizes earlier conjectures about the equivalence
of dynamic behavior in the two models and implies the indeterminacy of dynamic equilibria in the random matching model. As
in the overlapping generations model, the indeterminacy disappears if an arbitrarily small utility to holding money is introduced.
We introduce a different pricing mechanism, one that puts into sharp focus that agents are forward-looking when they interact.
Received: January 18, 2001; revised version: May 25, 2001 相似文献
13.
A simple characterization of majority rule 总被引:8,自引:0,他引:8
Summary. Assuming an odd number of voters, E. S. Maskin recently provided a characterization of majority rule based on full transitivity.
This paper characterizes majority rule with a set of axioms that includes two of Maskin's, dispenses with another, and contains
weak versions of his other two axioms. It allows the number of voters to be odd or even.
Received: December 23, 1998; revised version: May 10, 1999 相似文献
14.
Takashi Kamihigashi 《Economic Theory》2002,20(2):427-433
Summary. This note provides a simple proof of the necessity of the transversality condition for the differentiable reduced-form model.
The proof uses only an elementary perturbation argument without relying on dynamic programming. The proof makes it clear that,
contrary to common belief, the necessity of the transversality condition can be shown in a straightforward way.
Received: January 22, 2001; revised version: April 2, 2001 相似文献
15.
Bettina Klaus 《Economic Theory》2001,17(3):675-692
We study two allocation models. In the first model, we consider the problem of allocating an infinitely divisible commodity
among agents with single-dipped preferences. In the second model, a degenerate case of the first one, we study the allocation
of an indivisible object to a group of agents. We consider rules that satisfy Pareto efficiency, strategy-proofness, and in addition either the consistency property separability or the solidarity property population-monotonicity. We show that the class of rules that satisfy Pareto efficiency, strategy-proofness, and separability equals the class of rules that satisfy Pareto efficiency, strategy-proofness, and non-bossiness. We also provide characterizations of all rules satisfying Pareto efficiency, strategy-proofness, and either separability or population-monotonicity. Since any such rule consists for the largest part of serial-dictatorship components, we can interpret the characterizations
as impossibility results.
Received: September 29, 1999; revised version: March 22, 2000 相似文献
16.
We consider the problem of allocating a set of indivisible objects to agents in a fair and efficient manner. In a recent paper, Bogomolnaia and Moulin consider the case in which all agents have strict preferences, and propose the probabilistic serial (PS) mechanism; they define a new notion of efficiency, called ordinal efficiency, and prove that the probabilistic serial mechanism finds an envy-free ordinally efficient assignment. However, the restrictive assumption of strict preferences is critical to their algorithm. Our main contribution is an analogous algorithm for the full preference domain in which agents are allowed to be indifferent between objects. Our algorithm is based on a reinterpretation of the PS mechanism as an iterative algorithm to compute a “flow” in an associated network. In addition we show that on the full preference domain it is impossible for even a weak strategyproof mechanism to find a random assignment that is both ordinally efficient and envy-free. 相似文献
17.
Mark G. Guzman 《Economic Theory》2000,16(2):421-455
Summary. This paper analyzes the equilibrium growth paths of two economies that are identical in all respects, except for the organization
of their financial systems: in particular, one has a competitive banking system and the other has a monopolistic banking system.
In addition, the sources of inefficiencies, as a result of monopoly banking, and their relationship to the existence of credit
rationing are explored. Monopoly in banking tends to depress the equilibrium law of motion for the capital stock for either
of two reasons. When credit rationing exists, monopoly banks ration credit more heavily than competitive banks. When credit
is not rationed, the existence of monopoly banking leads to excessive monitoring of credit financed investment. Both of these
have adverse consequences for capital accumulation. In addition, monopoly banking is more likely to lead to credit rationing
than is competitive banking. Finally, the scope for development trap phenomena to arise is considered under both a competitive
and a monopolistic banking system.
Received: September 20, 1999; revised version: December 3, 1999 相似文献
18.
Income and wealth distribution in a simple model of growth 总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1
Gerhard Sorger 《Economic Theory》2000,16(1):23-42
Summary. This paper studies a deterministic one-sector growth model with a constant returns to scale production function and endogenous
labor supply. It is shown that the distribution of capital among the agents has an effect on the level of per-capita output.
There exists a continuum of stationary equilibria with different levels of per-capita output. If the elasticity of intertemporal
substitution is large, a higher output level can be achieved when income inequality is great, that is, when the income distribution
is strongly dispersed. If the elasticity of intertemporal substitution is low, the reverse relation holds. The paper shows
that countries with identical production technologies and identical preferences may have different GDP levels because wealth
is distributed differently among their inhabitants.
Received: January 29, 1999; revised version: October 4, 1999 相似文献
19.
Summary. Short-term contracts and exogenous productivity growth are introduced in a simple wage bargaining model. The equilibrium
utilities corresponding to militant union behaviour are independent of the contract length. Necessary and sufficient conditions
for monotonic convergence to a unique steady state are derived. Otherwise, cyclic behaviour of wage shares is inevitable.
A wage decrease can occur if strike is credible, but never when strike is not credible. In the limit, as time between bargaining
rounds vanishes, this paradox survives.
Received: September 3, 1998; revised version: February 10, 2000 相似文献
20.
Summary. One version of the Coase Theorem is, If property rights are fully allocated, competition leads to efficient allocations.
This version implies that the public goods problem can be solved by allocating property rights fully. We show that this mechanism
is not likely to work well in economies with global externalities because the privatized economy is highly susceptible to
strategic behavior: The free-rider problem manifests itself as a complementary monopoly problem in an associated private goods
economy. Thus, our work relates the validity of the Coase Theorem to the literature on the incentives for strategic behavior
in economies with complementarities.
Received: 12 May 1999; revised version: 9 July 1999 相似文献