首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
相似文献
 共查询到20条相似文献,搜索用时 31 毫秒
1.
We consider a sufficient condition for the nonemptiness of the weak core in a finite exchange economy where every commodity is available only in integer quantities. We show that if the aggregate upper contour set is discretely convex, then the weak core is nonempty. In addition, we give two sufficient conditions for the aggregate upper contour set to be discretely convex. One is that every upper contour set of every agent is M?M?-convex. The other is that the number of commodities is two and every agent’s preference relation is weakly monotone and discretely convex.  相似文献   

2.
3.
Existence and efficiency of general equilibrium with commodity money is investigated in an economy where N   commodities are traded at N(N−1)/2N(N1)/2 commodity-pairwise trading posts. Trade is a resource-using activity recovering transaction costs through the spread between bid (wholesale) and ask (retail) prices. Budget constraints, enforced at each trading post separately, imply demand for a carrier of value between trading posts. Existence of general equilibrium is established under conventional convexity and continuity conditions while structuring the price space to account for distinct bid and ask price ratios. Commodity money flows are identified as the difference between gross and net inter-post trades.  相似文献   

4.
S. Dahel  N. Giri  Y. Lepage 《Metrika》1994,41(1):363-374
LetX be ap-normal random vector with unknown mean and unknown covariance matrix and letX be partitioned asX=(X (1) ,X (2) , ...,X (r) ) whereX (j) is a subvector of dimensionp j such that j=1 r p j =p. We show that the tests, obtained by Dahel (1988), are locally minimax. These tests have been derived to confront Ho: =0 versusH 1: 0 on the basis of sample of sizeN, X 1, ..., XN, drawn fromX andr additional samples of sizeN j, U i (j) , i=1, ..., Nj, drawn fromX (1), ...X (r) respectively. We assume that the (r+1) samples are independent and thatN j>p j forj=0, 1, ..., r (N oN andp op). Whenr=2 andp=2, a Monte Carlo study is performed to compare these tests with the likelihood ratio test (LRT) given by Srivastava (1985). We also show that no locally most powerful invariant test exists for this problem.  相似文献   

5.
Conclusion By modelling the private sector on the basis of self-employment, rather than the wage employment assumed by Hare (1987), we are able to proceed without making strong restrictions on functional forms. Our main conclusion is that the supply multiplier equationis affected by the inclusion of the private sector. The immediate effect of an increase in state sector goods purchases by the government is that there is an equal reduction in the amount of state sector goods available for the household sector. This is assumed to affect household demand for private sector output and household supply of labour to the private sector (as well as affecting household labour to the state sector, as in the Barro-Grossman model). The change in labour supply to the private sector affects the supply of goods by the private sector. The net result is that an excess demand (or supply) is created for private sector output and so the price of this output rises (or falls). In general, a change in private sector price leads to a change in state sector labour supply and output, a result, which, by definition, does not occur if the private sector is not included in the model. Thus, the supply multiplier in general takes a different value from that found by Barro and Grossman.Given that the rate of change of labour supply to the state sector with respect to the price of the private sector good is negative we obtain the following conclusion. (a) If a marginal decrease in the availability of state output results in an excess supply of private sector output (before price changes), the supply multiplier is not as negative as in the Barro-Grossman model and may even be zero or positive. (b) If, however, an excess demand for private sector output is created, the supply multiplier is actually more negative than in the Barro-Grossman model. Should, instead, the rate of change of labour supply to the state sector with respect to the price of the private sector good be positive these conclusions are reversed, in the sense that the terms excess supply in (a) and excess demand in (b) are interchanged.(The views expressed in this paper should not necessarily be attributed to the Department of Trade and Industry.) We would like to thank an anonymous reference for helpful comments, particularly in pointing out an inconsistency in our treatment of the individual and the aggregate behaviour of households in an earlier version of the paper.  相似文献   

6.
Abstract In this paper, we focus on the following problem: given a financial market, modelled by a process , and a family of probability measures on , with N a positive integer and the time space, we search for financially meaningful conditions which are equivalent to the existence and uniqueness of an equivalent (local) martingale measure (EMM) Q such that the price process S has under Q the pre-specified finite-dimensional distributions of order N (N-dds) . We call these two equivalent properties, respectively, N -mixed no free lunch and market N -completeness. They are based on a classification of contingent claims with respect to their path-dependence on S and on the related notion of N-mixed strategy. Finally, we apply this approach to the Black-Scholes model with jumps, by showing a uniqueness result for its equivalent martingale measures set. Mathematics Subject Classification (2000): 60G48, 91B28 Journal of Economic Literature Classification: G12, D52  相似文献   

7.
Dr. C. C. Brown 《Metrika》1976,23(1):83-89
Summary The problem of testing the mean vector of the two dimensional circularly symmetrical normal distribution with unit variances, where the data consists of just one sample point inR 2, is examined for stability of -maximin criteria. If the null hypothesisH 0 is the one point set containing the origin and the alternative set equal to the whole ofR 2H 0, then the -maximin is not unique. If a zone of indifference I containingH 0 is introduced, then the problem of testingH 0 againstR 2 I can turn out to have a unique -maximin test. In the present paper we show a class of such I for which this is the case. We show further that, given any -maximin test for testingH 0 againstR 2H 0, there is a decreasing sequence of I , with intersection equal toH 0, for which the corresponding sequence of -maximin tests forH 0 againstR 2 I approaches a limit (in the usual weak star topology) which is not equivalent to .  相似文献   

8.
Jevons’s double coincidence of wants condition is derived as the result of household level transaction costs in general equilibrium where N   commodities are traded at (1/2)N(N−1)(1/2)N(N1) commodity-pairwise trading posts. Each household experiences a set-up cost on entering an additional trading post. Budget constraints are enforced at each trading post separately implying demand for a carrier of value between trading posts, commodity money. General equilibrium consists of prices so that each trading post clears. Existence and local uniqueness of commodity money in equilibrium can follow from the scale economy implied by the household set-up cost.  相似文献   

9.
The main idea developed in this paper is that rising excess demand for the labour force results in higher growth of wages over the notional rate of growth. The rationale is that employees change their jobs searching for higher wages, and employers are willing to offer higher pay in order to get additional workers. This relationship is highly nonlinear, and can be regarded as an extension of the idea known as the Phillips curve to the area of negative rate of unemployment. Additionally, one can observe that if the disequilibrium intensity in the labour market is small, its changes cause stronger reactions of wages in strategic branches than in the remaining sectors of the economy. It is similar to the situation of excess demand for labour. If there is a high rate of unemployment, reductions of wages affect more branches of secondary importance for the economy. The empirical investigation is based on Polish data covering the time period from 1964 through 1984. As excess demand for labour is unobservable, a proxy is used as an indicator of disequilibrium. It is introduced to the equation explaining the rate of growth of average wages, in addition to the rate of productivity growth of labour and the rate of inflation. Estimates are derived for 10 industry branches and sectors of the economy. The results confirm the initial hypothesis.  相似文献   

10.
The literature on the characterization of aggregate excess and market demand has generated three types of results: global, local, or ‘at a point’. In this note, we study the relationship between the last two approaches. We prove that within the class of functions satisfying standard conditions and whose Jacobian matrix is negative semi-definite, only n/2+1n/2+1 agents are needed for the ‘at’ decomposition. We ask whether, within the same class, the ‘around’ decomposition also requires only n/2+1n/2+1 agents.  相似文献   

11.
Summary The estimation of parameter in the type of distributionf(x)=b x –1 /b exp (–x b (/b),x>0, is considered, when several outliers of the type , ,r=1,2, ...,k, are present in the data. The estimates of as well as of 's are put in the closed form. Special cases, Weibull, Gamma and Exponential are considered for the case of single outlier. Actual estimates are calculated from the generated samples of size 2 and 3 for the Weibull and Exponential.  相似文献   

12.
W. Stadje 《Metrika》1988,35(1):93-97
LetP be a probability measure on ℝ andI x be the set of alln-dimensional rectangles containingx. If for allx ∈ ℝn and θ ∈ ℝ the inequality holds,P is a normal distributioin with mean 0 or the unit mass at 0. The result generalizes Teicher’s (1961) maximum likelihood characterization of the normal density to a characterization ofN(0, σ2) amongall distributions (including those without density). The m.l. principle used is that of Scholz (1980).  相似文献   

13.
Si considera la classe delle funzioni realiF(x,y) definite inS×S, conSR N , che soddisfano per ognix,yS la condizione di monotoniaF(x,y)+F(y,x)0. Indebolendo la precedente disuguaglianza si introducono classi di funzioni monotone generalizzate e, supponendo soddisfatta una opportuna condizione di omogeneità, si caratterizzano tali funzioni in base alla struttura del segno delle funzioni x, v (t, s) = F(x + tv, x + sv), x S, v R N \{0}. Infine dopo aver definite le funzioni F-differenziabili, si introducono classi di funzioni conversse generalizzate, rispetto ad F, e si studiano i collegamenti tra queste classi e la monotonia generalizzata diF.
Summary We consider the class of real valued functionF(x,y) defined inS×S, withSR N , satisfying x,yS the monotone conditionF(x,y)+F(y,x)0. Weakening the previous inequality we introduce the class of quasi-monotone, pseudo-monotone and strictly pseudo-monotone functions. Under a suitable assumption of homogeneity we characterize the generalized monotone functions studying the sign structure of the functions x, v (t, s) = F(x + tv, x + sv), x S, v R N \{0}.Finally by means of the notion ofF-differentiability we introduce new classes of generalized convex functions (with respect toF) and we study the relationship between these classes and the generalized monotonicity ofF.


Questa ricerca è stata parzialmente finanziata dal Ministero per l'Università e la Ricerca Scientifica.  相似文献   

14.
Se, essendof la funzione obiettivo del problema, {x k } e {f(x k )} sono le successioni delle approssimazioni rispettivamente di una soluzione ottimax * e dell' ottimof(x *) generate da un noto algoritmo di direzioni ammissibili a parametri antizigzag k , mostriamo che per avere (a) lim k f(x *)=f(x *) basta assumere lim k k =0. Inoltre, ove si assuma in più la stretta convessità dif, si ha anche (b) lim k x k =x *. Da quest'ultima condizione deriviamo infine specifiche ipotesi, in ordine alla (b), per il caso particolare del problema di trasporto stocastico.
Summary The aim of the present paper is to analyze, without differentiability of the objective functionf, the convergence of a known «feasible directions» algorithm for constrained optimization problems having the constraints linear [8], 6.5.2.In these circumstances (i.e. iff is not differentiable) one must, almost in general, verify some preliminary conditions to obtain convergence [4]. Nevertheless, this work is not always easy to accomplish particularly in absence of differentiability.Here, we establish that under the convexity assumption forf, the only condition lim k k =0, where the k are the antizigzag parameters, suffices to obtain the convergence of the algorithm, i.e. lim k f(x k )=opt., thex k being the approximate solutions to problem. The proof is obtained by application of the Th. 24.5, [6]. Successively, we consider the question if one has also the convergence of {x k } to optimal solution. By using now the Cor. 27.2.2, [6], we establish, for this purpose, that under an additional general qualification forf — precisely the strict convexity — the convergence of {x k } is also stated. Finally, we examine the above property for the stochastic transportation problem [1] for which we indicate special conditions in order to verify the latter convergence property.


pervenuto il 28-4-82  相似文献   

15.
Consider a stochastic frontier model with one-sided inefficiency u, and suppose that the scale of u depends on some variables (firm characteristics) z. A one-step model specifies both the stochastic frontier and the way in which u depends on z, and can be estimated in a single step, for example by maximum likelihood. This is in contrast to a two-step procedure, where the first step is to estimate a standard stochastic frontier model, and the second step is to estimate the relationship between (estimated) u and z.In this paper we propose a class of one-step models based on the scaling property that u equals a function of z times a one-sided error u * whose distribution does not depend on z. We explain theoretically why two-step procedures are biased, and we present Monte Carlo evidence showing that the bias can be very severe. This evidence argues strongly for one-step models whenever one is interested in the effects of firm characteristics on efficiency levels.  相似文献   

16.
17.
To study equilibria we describe an economy by its distribution of consumers' preferences and endowments. All preferences are smooth and weakly convex. Demand of an economy need not be single valued, but there is an open dense set of economies for which demand is a C1-function in a neighborhood of the equilibrium prices. We call an economy regular if its excess demand is transversal to zero. A regular economy has locally unique equilibria. It is shown that regular economies form an open dense set on which the equilibrium price correspondence varies continuously and the number of equilibria is locally constant.  相似文献   

18.
Zusammenfassung Es sei A: R n R n eine Abbildung mit für jedes sei einn-dimensionaler Zufallsvektor. Wir beschreiben die Klasse aller TransformationenA, für die unabhängige, nachN(0, 1) verteilte Komponenten hat, sofern nur die KomponentenX 1,...,X n des Zufallsvektors ebenfalls unabhängig und identish Gaußisch verteilt sind mit Erwartungswert Null und Varianz 1. Weiter sind Bedingungen angegeben, die sicherstellen, daß nachN(O, 2) verteilte KomponentenX 1,...,X n hat, sofern dieX 1,...,X n unabhängig und und identisch verteilt sind. Zwei vonBeer undLukacs behandelte Transformationen sind Spezialfälle der hier untersuchten Transformationen.
Summary Let A: R n R n be a transformation with the property for every . We consider a random vector and characterize the class of all transformationsA such that has independentN (0, 1) distributed componentsY 1,...,Y n if has the same distribution. Furthermore in the paper there are given conditions which ensure that hasN(O, 2 distributed components if and are identically distributed and the componentsX 1,...,X n are independent, identically distributed random variables. Two of the transformations tried byBeer andLukacs are special cases of our transformations.
  相似文献   

19.
Since demand for hospital services is subject to substantial variability, the relationship between uncertain demand, excess capacity, hospital costs and performance should be investigated thoroughly. In this paper a waiting time indicator to proxy hospital standby capacity is incorporated into a multi-product translog cost function for Belgian general care hospitals. The indicator is derived from queuing theory and improves on the conventionally used (inverse of the) occupancy rate. The multi-product stochastic frontier specification allows calculation of cost elasticities and marginal cost of seven hospital departments, as well as the degree of economies of scale and scope and enables identification of differences in efficiency.
Mike SmetEmail:
  相似文献   

20.
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号