共查询到20条相似文献,搜索用时 0 毫秒
1.
Fraser Neil 《International Review of Applied Economics》1987,1(2):209-224
This article reviews Swedish economic policy since 1960 in the light of the trade union's Rehn-Meidner model. The arguments of economists who blame the crisis of the Swedish economy in the 1970s on that model are critically reviewed. The maintenance of full employment is analysed. The policies of the Social Democratic government since 1982 are found to be significantly at variance with the Rehn-Meidner model leading to a high risk of wage-push inflation. It is suggested that the British labour movement has lessons to learn from Swedish experience and the Rehn-Meidner model in particular. 相似文献
2.
3.
4.
We study the effect of place-based industrial policy on economic development, focusing on the establishment of Special Economic Zones (SEZ) in China. We use data from a panel of Chinese (prefecture-level) cities from 1988 to 2010. Our difference-in-difference estimation exploits the variation in the establishment of SEZ across time and space. We find that the establishment of a state-level SEZ is associated with an increase in the level of GDP of about 20 %. This finding is confirmed with alternative specifications and in a sub-sample of inland provinces, where the selection of cities to host the zones was based on administrative criteria. The main channel is a positive effect on physical capital accumulation, although SEZ also have a positive effect on total factor productivity and human capital investments. We also investigate whether there are spillover effects of SEZ on neighboring regions or cities further away. We find positive and often significant spillover effects. 相似文献
5.
Carlos Peraita 《Applied economics》2013,45(16):1885-1898
Using data from the 1994 European Community Household Panel Survey, the author examines who receives formal firm-sponsored training in Spain. The author finds that the distribution of firm-sponsored training in the work force is uneven and concentrated among more skilled workers in the upper deciles of the wage distribution. The data show that the likelihood of receiving firm-sponsored training for a low education employee is much lower. Also, the better-educated employees in high wage occupations of the largest establishments have higher probabilities of receiving specific training. Spain has a highly regulated labour market, and the labour market frictions and institutions compress and distort the structure of wages. However, the results suggest that the highly compressed wage structure do not provide firms with the incentive to invest in general training. 相似文献
6.
Enrico Marelli 《International Review of Economics》2006,53(1):16-48
This paper begins with a review of the literature on the labour market’s impact of globalisation.
An interesting case-study is provided by the province of Brescia, an industrial area in Northern Italy, where both de-localisation
and immigration have been two important means of reducing the pressure of labour demand on the locally scarce human resources.
The conclusion is that, in order to preserve competitive positions in the long run, it is worthy to consider the qualitative
consequences, e.g. the indispensable changes in the structure of production, rather than focusing on the quantitative effects
on domestic employment.
This paper was presented at the International Conference on “Developments in Economic Theory and Policy, Institutions and
European Integration”, Bilbao, 15–17 July, 2004. It is part of a wider research: see the Working Paper by Albertini and Marelli
(2003). The sections prepared by S.Albertini, referring to organisational change and human resources management implications,
are not included in this final paper. I am grateful to anonymous referees for helpful comments. 相似文献
7.
Donald B. Keesing 《Journal of development economics》1975,2(1):1-32
Based on China's recent experience, positive lessons are suggested that could potentially be transplanted to other countries, especially socialist developing countries. Six lessons and three corollaries are put forward. The first three lessons relate to principles of income distribution, motivation, and guidance in decentralized decision making: a ‘fair-shares’ principle of distribution, a way to cut the Gordian knot of the problem of success indicators, etc. The fourth lesson involves price stability and the aggregate balance between supply and demand. Other lessons treat sector priorities, industrial decentralization, and small-scale rural industry. These Chinese approaches increase some attractions and reduce some shortcomings of socialism. 相似文献
8.
Do market-oriented economic reforms result in higher levels of human well-being? This article studies the impact of macro-level institutional and infrastructure reforms on the economic, educational and health dimensions of human well-being among 25 transition economies. We use panel data econometrics based on the LSDVC technique to analyse the effects of market-oriented reforms on the human development index (HDI), as a measure of human well-being, from 1992 to 2007. The results show the complexity of reform impacts in transition countries. They show that institutional and economic reforms led to positive economic effect and significant impacts on other dimensions of human development. We find some positive economic impacts from infrastructure sectors reforms. However, not every reform measure appears to generate positive impacts. Large-scale privatizations show negative effects in health and economic outcomes. The overall results show the importance of the interaction among different reform measures and the combined effect of these on human development. 相似文献
9.
The expansion of nature reserves is an important public policy strategy for the protection of biological diversity. In this paper, the authors use integer programming model structures derived from Location Set Covering Problem and Maximal Covering Location Problem approaches of location science as tools for selectively augmenting nature reserve sites for special status species protection. The linear programming models presented incorporate the following: biological constraints in the form of species' area needs; economic constraints in the form of opportunity costs of converting smaller administrative districts into nature reserves; and spatial constraints in the form of required connectivity among districts in site selection. The construction of a taxonomic data set for Thailand enables the implementation of the models, the comparison of results and evaluation of the differences in outcomes. The models build upon the existing nature reserve network in Thailand and suggest various public policy options that would augment the reserves for enhancing species protection and for possibly improving national conservation efforts at lowest costs. 相似文献
10.
Rodrigo Troncoso 《Empirical Economics》2011,41(1):183-197
Empirical evidence of the credit channel of monetary policy often relies on the observance of flight to quality during monetary
tightening. The identification assumption is that the typically smaller firms facing financing constraints, are disproportionally
affected by the stance of monetary policy. I argue that when credit constrains are widespread, as may be the case in Emerging
Markets, flight to quality should not be expected during monetary contractions. Indeed, in my model, among constrained firms,
those with tighter financing constraints are less responsive to monetary conditions. I find evidence supporting my model in
a sample of firms from the Emerging Market of Chile. 相似文献
11.
We use probit recession forecasting models to assess the ability of economic policy uncertainty indexes developed by Baker et al. (2013) to predict future US recessions. The model specifications include policy indexes on their own, and in combination with financial variables, such as interest rate spreads, stock returns and stock market volatility. Both in-sample and out-of-sample analysis suggests that the policy uncertainty indexes are statistically and economically significant in forecasting recessions at the horizons beyond five quarters. The index based on newspaper reports emerges as the best predictor, outperforming the term spread at the longer forecast horizons. 相似文献
12.
This paper examines the degree to which world price signals have been transmitted into domestic prices for eight countries and ten commodities, a total of 31 country/commodity pairs. The main characteristic of these countries was that they all undertook substantial policy reforms during the mid‐1980s to early 1990s. The paper investigates the effect of reforms on the speed at which signals were transmitted to domestic markets and on the extent of price transmission. We find that Chile, Mexico, and Argentina are the only countries whose domestic commodity markets were integrated with world markets. For the remaining cases (Ghana, Madagascar, Indonesia, Egypt, and Colombia) in only a few country/commodity pairs is there some passthrough of world price changes. In terms of the effects of policy reforms, in the majority of the cases the hypothesis of a structural break following the reform year is rejected. 相似文献
13.
Axel Börsch-Supan 《Empirica》2013,40(3):397-407
This keynote speech draws three broad lessons to turn the challenges of population ageing into chances: Lesson number one is that the quantity effects of adding more labour into our ageing economies are very large. To exploit them, one has to use the entire spectrum of labour market policies: earlier labour market entry, later retirement age, higher female labour force participation, and lower unemployment. Lesson number two is that there is a positive and enforcing effect of pension reform. A pension regime that alleviates the tax burden of the younger generation creates higher productive capacity. The third lesson is on behavioural effects. Some strengthen reform but they are dominated by opposition effects, such as taking advantage of loopholes, withdrawal of labour supply, or simple within-household substitution. Negative behavioural effects can be minimised by informing people better about the chances and challenges of population ageing, and by de-mystifying false beliefs about ageing. 相似文献
14.
15.
Integrating the internal and external labour markets 总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1
16.
Michael H. Böheim 《Empirica》2011,38(3):315-330
The financial crisis brought great challenges also for competition policy. The aim of this paper is to summarize the most important insights for competition policy that could be derived from the turbulent period 2008–2010. The financial crisis is seen as project that demanded sound management from competition policy and enforcement. The insights will be presented in the instructive form of ‘lessons learnt’ which represents a common approved project management technique. We come to the result that the financial crisis is not the result of ‘too much competition’, but of regulatory failure and that the main answers to the financial crisis have to come from ‘smart regulation’. The relaxation of competition policy would be the wrong policy response in troubled times since competition policy can play an important role in bringing the crisis economy back on track. In contrast to banking we see no economic rationale for rescue packages for other economic sectors by referring to systemic risk. The renaissance of industrial policy is viewed with great skepticism since empirical evidence shows that the effort of picking ‘winners’ all too often results in saving ‘losers’. 相似文献
17.
Search equilibrium models in the Economics of Information concern themselves exclusively with consumer ignorance of the prices that different firms charge. Legal regulation dealing with information, on the other hand, concerns itself primarily with contact terms. In particular, firms are often required to warrant against product related defects on the supposed ground that firms respond to consumer ignorance only by degrading contract quality. This paper is the beginning of an attempt to make the Economics of Information useful to policymakers. It models a market for warranties under imperfect information and shows that firms are more likely to respond to consumer ignorance by raising prices for the warranties that consumers prefer rather than deleting warranties from consumer contracts. Hence, policymakers should be concerned more with reducing supracompetitive prices than with “improving” contract quality. 相似文献
18.
In its waning days, the Clinton administration decided that it was appropriate to regulate mercury emissions from power plants.
The incoming Bush administration had to decide how best to regulate these emissions. The Bush administration offered two approaches
for regulating mercury emissions from power plants. The first was to establish uniform emission rates across utilities, as
mandated by the 1990 Amendments. The second was to establish a cap on mercury emissions while allowing emissions trading in
order to reduce the cost of achieving the goal. This paper presents the first cost-benefit analysis of this issue that takes
account of IQ benefits. We find that the benefits of the mercury regulation are likely to fall short of the cost. This assessment
is based on a number of assumptions that are highly uncertain. The finding of negative net benefits is robust to many, though
not all, reasonable variations in the model assumptions. We also find that the emissions trading proposal is roughly $15 billion
less expensive than the command-and-control proposal.
Mr. Gayer is associate professor of public policy at Georgetown University and a visiting scholar at the American Enterprise
Institute. Mr. Hahn is co-founder and executive director of the American Enterprise Institute-Brookings Joint Center for Regulatory
Studies and a scholar at AEI. We would like to thank Mary Jo Krolewski, Leonard Levin, Joel Schwartz, Anne Smith, Nik Wada,
and Chris Whipple for helpful comments and Jordan Connors, Laura Goodman and Molly Wells for valuable research assistance.
The views expressed in this paper represent those of the authors and do not necessarily represent the views of the institutions
with which they are affiliated. 相似文献
19.
Rudolf Winter-Ebmer 《Applied economics》2013,45(9):849-857
Theoritical explanations for wage discrimination collapse in the long run, because competition should drive discriminations firms out of the market. In product markets with imperfect competition employes with a taste for discrimination might survive, None the less inthis case long-run efffects are also unclear, unless some monopsonistic power in the labour market is involved. Monopsony in the labour market, on the other hand, has received very little attention in the literature. The paper tries to pick up this long negleted issue, looking at the impact of concentration in output markets and local labour markets on wage discrimination by sex in Austria. As limited workers' mobility enables employers to define their own local labour markets,special attention is given to married women, whose geographical mobility is known to be very low. 相似文献
20.
We study Virginia's suffrage from the early-17th century until the American Revolution using an analytical narrative and econometric analysis of unique data on franchise restrictions. First, we hold that suffrage changes reflected labour market dynamics. Indeed, Virginia's liberal institutions initially served to attract indentured servants from England who were needed in the labour-intensive tobacco farming but deteriorated once worker demand subsided and planters replaced white workers with slaves. Second, we argue that Virginia's suffrage was also the result of political bargaining influenced by shifting societal coalitions. We show that new politically influential coalitions of freemen and then of small and large slave-holding farmers emerged in the second half of the 17th and early-18th centuries, respectively. These coalitions were instrumental in reversing the earlier democratic institutions. Our main contribution stems from integrating the labour markets and bargaining/coalitions arguments, thus proving a novel theoretical and empirical explanation for institutional change. 相似文献