全文获取类型
收费全文 | 615篇 |
免费 | 10篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 74篇 |
工业经济 | 32篇 |
计划管理 | 89篇 |
经济学 | 179篇 |
综合类 | 15篇 |
运输经济 | 5篇 |
旅游经济 | 5篇 |
贸易经济 | 144篇 |
农业经济 | 15篇 |
经济概况 | 67篇 |
出版年
2022年 | 3篇 |
2021年 | 3篇 |
2020年 | 5篇 |
2019年 | 10篇 |
2018年 | 7篇 |
2017年 | 12篇 |
2016年 | 15篇 |
2015年 | 14篇 |
2014年 | 15篇 |
2013年 | 69篇 |
2012年 | 35篇 |
2011年 | 17篇 |
2010年 | 25篇 |
2009年 | 12篇 |
2008年 | 28篇 |
2007年 | 20篇 |
2006年 | 19篇 |
2005年 | 16篇 |
2004年 | 6篇 |
2003年 | 5篇 |
2002年 | 21篇 |
2001年 | 12篇 |
2000年 | 14篇 |
1999年 | 12篇 |
1998年 | 11篇 |
1997年 | 10篇 |
1996年 | 7篇 |
1995年 | 13篇 |
1994年 | 4篇 |
1993年 | 4篇 |
1992年 | 13篇 |
1991年 | 9篇 |
1990年 | 7篇 |
1989年 | 11篇 |
1987年 | 3篇 |
1986年 | 10篇 |
1985年 | 3篇 |
1984年 | 10篇 |
1983年 | 8篇 |
1982年 | 4篇 |
1981年 | 13篇 |
1980年 | 7篇 |
1979年 | 12篇 |
1978年 | 3篇 |
1977年 | 4篇 |
1975年 | 8篇 |
1972年 | 3篇 |
1935年 | 3篇 |
1934年 | 6篇 |
1890年 | 2篇 |
排序方式: 共有625条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
1.
U.‐G. Gerdtham P. Lundborg C. H. Lyttkens P. Nystedt 《The Scandinavian journal of economics》2016,118(1):25-48
We apply a twin design to examine the relationship between health and education and income. The estimated associations between health and education and income, controlling for unobserved endowments, at the twin‐pair level, are lower than estimates obtained via ordinary least‐squares (OLS) on the same sample. Thus, OLS‐based effects of education and income are biased, exaggerating the contribution of education and income to health inequality. The main part of health inequality is explained by within‐twin‐pair fixed effects, incorporating family background and genetic inheritance. It appears that education and income policies have less to offer for reducing health inequality than is usually assumed. 相似文献
2.
The importance of international trade to the Malaysian economy can hardly be exaggerated. Trade represents a lifeline for the Malaysian economy. Export‐oriented industrialization in the 1990s converted the labor‐surplus economy into a labor‐deficit one and then back to a labor‐surplus one in 2000 and beyond. The incidence of poverty has fallen by half since the early 1980s. Trade has also contributed much to the structural transformation and modernization of the economy. Had Malaysia been a closed economy, Malaysia would have shared the same fate as some other less developed countries that remain economically backward. Its external trade policy has paved the way for greater inflows of foreign direct investment, as foreign direct investors are not so much interested in serving the small domestic market as serving the vast external market. The large inflows of foreign direct investment have conferred positive effects on the domestic economy. This has meant significant improvements in the overall living standards for the Malaysians. Internationalization has provided employment opportunities, thereby raising their living standards through higher and more stable earnings. © 2009 Wiley Periodicals, Inc. 相似文献
3.
A. Bilimovič O. Morgenstern O. Lange H. Zassenhaus R. Nurkse W. L. Valk G. Haberler W. Röpke U. Ricci M. St. Braun K. H. Stephans A. Gerschenkron G. U. Papi H. Bayer J. Tinbergen N. W. Dolinski E. Schiff J. H. Fürth O. Veit A. W. Stonier J. Kraft M. Ginsberg F. Kaufmann 《Journal of Economics》1934,5(3):380-430
Ohne ZusammenfassungAus dem Italienischen übersetzt von M. St. Braun, WienAus dem Italienischen übersetzt von E. Allina, WienAus dem Russischen übersetzt von A. GerschenkronÜbersetzt von Paul Brüll, Wien. 相似文献
4.
Robert U. Ayres 《Environmental and Resource Economics》1995,6(3):207-230
Economists are increasingly interested in forecasting future costs and benefits of policies for dealing with materials/energy fluxes, polluting emissions and environmental impacts on various scales, from sectoral to global. Computable general equilibrium (CGE) models are currently popular because they project demand and industrial structure into the future, along an equilibrium path. But they are applicable only to the extent that structural changes occur in or near equilibrium, independent of radical technological (or social) change. The alternative tool for analyzing economic implications of scenario assumptions is to use Leontief-type Input-Output (I-O) models. I-O models are unable to endogenize structural shifts (changing I-O coefficients). However, this can be a virtue when considering radical rather than incremental shifts. Postulated I-O tables can be used independently to check the internal consistency of scenarios. Or I-O models can be used to generate scenarios by linking them to econometric macro-drivers (which can, in principle, be CGE models). Explicit process analysis can be integrated, in principle, with I-O models. This hybrid scheme provides a natural means of satisfying physical constraints, especially the first and second laws of thermodynamics. This is important, to avoid constructing scenarios based on physically impossible processes. Process analysis is really the only available tool for constructing physically plausible alternative future I-O tables, and generating materials/energy and waste emissions coefficients. Explicit process analysis also helps avoid several problems characteristic of pure CGE or I-O models, viz. (1) aggregation errors (2) inability to handle arbitrary combinations of co-product and co-input relationships and (3) inability to reflect certain non-linearities such as internal feedback loops. 相似文献
5.
Synopsis We describe the first effort at creating a global ex-vessel fish price database, which is required for understanding the economic
behavior of participants in the world’s fisheries. We demonstrate potential applications of the database by linking it to
a spatially defined catch database, which makes it possible to attach landed values to species in both time and space. This
is the first database available publicly where interested members of the public, researchers and managers can easily find
and access ex-vessel prices of the world’s major commercial fish species. Preliminary results indicate that the average real
price of a number of species have declined between 1950 and 2002. The estimated landed value of fish globally, in year 2000
dollars, was about US$24 billion in 1950. It increased steadily to about US$90 billion in the early 1970s, reached a peak
of US$100 billion at the end of the 1980s, and declined to about US$80 billion in 2000. The top 15 fishing countries cumulatively
account for 79% of total real landed value, with Japan leading, even though the value of its landings has been declining.
相似文献
6.
7.
8.
The problem of allocating the sample numbers to the strata in multivariate stratified surveys, where, apart from the cost involved in enumerating the selected individuals in the sample, there is an overhead cost associated with each stratum, has been formulated as a non-linear programming problem. The variances of the posterior distributions of the means of various characters are put to restraints and the total cost is minimized. The main problem is broken into subproblems for each of which the objective function turns out to be convex. When the number of subproblems happens to be large an approach has been indicated for obtaining an approximate solution by solving only a small number of subproblems. 相似文献
9.
Reinsurance is available for a reinsurance premium that is determined according to a convex premium principle H. The first insurer selects the reinsurance coverage that maximizes its expected utility. No conditions are imposed on the reinsurer's payment. The optimality condition involves the gradient of H. For several combinations of H and the first insurer's utility function, closed-form formulas for the optimal reinsurance are given. If H is a zero utility principle (for example, an exponential principle or an expectile principle), it is shown, by means of Borch's Theorem, that the optimal reinsurer's payment is a function of the total claim amount and that this function satisfies the so-called 1-Lipschitz condition. Frequently, authors impose these two conclusions as hypotheses at the outset. 相似文献
10.
Reinhardt U 《Medical economics》1992,69(21):126-8, 130, 137-8 passim