全文获取类型
收费全文 | 206篇 |
免费 | 17篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 123篇 |
工业经济 | 11篇 |
计划管理 | 30篇 |
经济学 | 23篇 |
旅游经济 | 2篇 |
贸易经济 | 7篇 |
农业经济 | 3篇 |
经济概况 | 24篇 |
出版年
2024年 | 1篇 |
2023年 | 2篇 |
2020年 | 1篇 |
2019年 | 1篇 |
2018年 | 4篇 |
2017年 | 4篇 |
2016年 | 3篇 |
2015年 | 8篇 |
2014年 | 3篇 |
2013年 | 11篇 |
2012年 | 9篇 |
2011年 | 8篇 |
2010年 | 11篇 |
2009年 | 11篇 |
2008年 | 7篇 |
2007年 | 8篇 |
2006年 | 7篇 |
2005年 | 6篇 |
2004年 | 7篇 |
2002年 | 3篇 |
1999年 | 2篇 |
1998年 | 1篇 |
1997年 | 4篇 |
1996年 | 4篇 |
1995年 | 5篇 |
1994年 | 7篇 |
1993年 | 5篇 |
1992年 | 6篇 |
1991年 | 4篇 |
1990年 | 7篇 |
1989年 | 8篇 |
1988年 | 5篇 |
1987年 | 9篇 |
1986年 | 7篇 |
1985年 | 5篇 |
1984年 | 7篇 |
1983年 | 3篇 |
1982年 | 3篇 |
1981年 | 3篇 |
1980年 | 4篇 |
1979年 | 3篇 |
1977年 | 1篇 |
1973年 | 1篇 |
1972年 | 1篇 |
1969年 | 1篇 |
1968年 | 1篇 |
1967年 | 1篇 |
排序方式: 共有223条查询结果,搜索用时 10 毫秒
11.
12.
We develop a new model of multimarket trading to explain the differences in the foreign share of trading volume of internationally cross‐listed stocks. The model predicts that the trading volume of a cross‐listed stock is proportionally higher on the exchange in which the cross‐listed asset returns have greater correlation with returns of other assets traded on that market. We find robust empirical support for this prediction using stock return and volume data on 251 non‐U.S. stocks cross‐listed on major U.S. exchanges. 相似文献
13.
14.
Recreation researchers have considered coping behaviors one possible explanation for wilderness recreationists' high overall satisfaction levels despite reports of visitor over-crowding and other social conditions exceeding acceptable levels. Studies of recreationists' use of behavioral coping and cognitive coping mechanisms have had mixed results. This study used field-based interviews and surveys to identify coping behavior by hikers in the wilderness areas of New York's Adirondack Park. Findings indicate that wilderness hikers develop complex and variable strategies of coping behavior to maintain multiple satisfactions. 相似文献
15.
Stocks with large increases in call (put) implied volatilities over the previous month tend to have high (low) future returns. Sorting stocks ranked into decile portfolios by past call implied volatilities produces spreads in average returns of approximately 1% per month, and the return differences persist up to six months. The cross section of stock returns also predicts option implied volatilities, with stocks with high past returns tending to have call and put option contracts that exhibit increases in implied volatility over the next month, but with decreasing realized volatility. These predictability patterns are consistent with rational models of informed trading. 相似文献
16.
The Term Structure of Real Rates and Expected Inflation 总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1
Changes in nominal interest rates must be due to either movements in real interest rates, expected inflation, or the inflation risk premium. We develop a term structure model with regime switches, time‐varying prices of risk, and inflation to identify these components of the nominal yield curve. We find that the unconditional real rate curve in the United States is fairly flat around 1.3%. In one real rate regime, the real term structure is steeply downward sloping. An inflation risk premium that increases with maturity fully accounts for the generally upward sloping nominal term structure. 相似文献
17.
CRAIG DOIDGE G. ANDREW KAROLYI KARL V. LINS DARIUS P. MILLER RENÉ M. STULZ 《The Journal of Finance》2009,64(1):425-466
This paper investigates how a foreign firm's decision to cross-list on a U.S. stock exchange is related to the consumption of private benefits of control by its controlling shareholders. Theory has proposed that when private benefits are high, controlling shareholders are less likely to choose to cross-list in the United States because of constraints on the consumption of private benefits resulting from such listings. Using several proxies for private benefits related to the control and cash flow ownership rights of controlling shareholders, we find support for this hypothesis with a sample of more than 4,000 firms from 31 countries. 相似文献
18.
ANDREW BURRELL 《Economic Outlook》1992,16(5):51-57
This Economic Outlook presents a forecast produced on a large, with more than 700 variables, econometric model of the UK developed over the last 25 years by researchers at the Centre for Economic Forecasting. As macroeconomic theory is not static, new equations are regularly incorporated into the model framework to replace, or augment, older ones with the aim of improving our understanding of the UK economy. The best way to assess the impact of changes to the model is to perform a series of simulation exercises and compare the results of the system as a whole with established theoretical priors. In this paper we discuss the most recent changes to the structure of the model and describe the results from four simulation exercises. 相似文献
19.
ANDREW MEARMAN 《American journal of economics and sociology》2011,70(2):480-510
This paper attempts to engage with the established debate on the nature of heterodox economics. However, it starts from the position that previous attempts to classify and identify heterodox economics have been biased towards a priori definition. The paper aims to inform the discussion of the nature of heterodoxy with some empirical analysis. The paper examines survey data collected from a small/medium‐sized sample of AHE members on the core concepts in economics. The paper applies factor analysis to the data. It also applies principles of biological taxonomy, and thence cluster analysis to the problem. The paper finds that within the self‐identified community of self‐identified heterodox economists there is little agreement as to whether members are pluralist, or what their attitude is to the mainstream. Indeed, there is little agreement on any core concepts or principles. The paper argues that there is little structure to heterodox economics beyond that provided by pre‐existing (or constituent) schools of thought. Based on this study, heterodox economics appears a complex web of interacting individuals and as a group is a fuzzy set. These results would lead us to question further strict distinctions between heterodox, mainstream and pluralist economists. 相似文献
20.
The fall in the personal sector savings ratio to a record low last year has been a major factor behind the rapid growth of domestic demand in the past two years and the associated deterioration in the current account. It is also a major uncertainty in the Chancellor's Budget judgement. Existing econometric relationships for the consumption function have failed to predict the fall in personal savings over the past few years. Possible explanations include statistical error, the effects of financial deregulation, the housing boom, expectations of higher growth in incomes, and demographic influences. In this Viewpoint, we report on a new consumption function that successfully explains the decline in savings. It provides evidence of a major demographic influence resulting from the decline in the proportion of the population in the 45–64 age cohort, the main savers in society. Subsidiary effects arise from the boom in house prices, and statistical mis-measurement. The equation predicts an appreciable revival of savings over the next few years as the 45–64 age cohort grows again. These shifts in demographic structure reflect the after-effects of the Second World War. This new evidence suggests that the Chancellor has done quite enough to ensure a slowdown in consumption, and that he would be ill-advised to heed calls for special measures to boost savings. By contrast, well conceived tax changes that remove microeconomic distortions in the tax system (perhaps moving in the direction of an expenditure tax) would improve the tax structure, and may well increase the scope for tax cuts in future budgets. Our new consumption function also lends weight to the Chancellor's argument that the current account deficit is not a source of concern, insofar as it arises from a shift in savings associated with demographic changes that will be reversed in due course. 相似文献