全文获取类型
收费全文 | 7138篇 |
免费 | 315篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 961篇 |
工业经济 | 313篇 |
计划管理 | 1358篇 |
经济学 | 2128篇 |
综合类 | 43篇 |
运输经济 | 129篇 |
旅游经济 | 125篇 |
贸易经济 | 1646篇 |
农业经济 | 251篇 |
经济概况 | 490篇 |
邮电经济 | 9篇 |
出版年
2024年 | 8篇 |
2023年 | 125篇 |
2022年 | 98篇 |
2021年 | 127篇 |
2020年 | 233篇 |
2019年 | 297篇 |
2018年 | 447篇 |
2017年 | 520篇 |
2016年 | 452篇 |
2015年 | 253篇 |
2014年 | 330篇 |
2013年 | 1192篇 |
2012年 | 390篇 |
2011年 | 384篇 |
2010年 | 353篇 |
2009年 | 311篇 |
2008年 | 263篇 |
2007年 | 201篇 |
2006年 | 191篇 |
2005年 | 178篇 |
2004年 | 124篇 |
2003年 | 130篇 |
2002年 | 109篇 |
2001年 | 78篇 |
2000年 | 57篇 |
1999年 | 57篇 |
1998年 | 65篇 |
1997年 | 39篇 |
1996年 | 32篇 |
1995年 | 20篇 |
1994年 | 28篇 |
1993年 | 17篇 |
1992年 | 21篇 |
1991年 | 22篇 |
1990年 | 13篇 |
1989年 | 19篇 |
1988年 | 10篇 |
1987年 | 7篇 |
1986年 | 10篇 |
1985年 | 22篇 |
1984年 | 24篇 |
1983年 | 21篇 |
1982年 | 18篇 |
1981年 | 16篇 |
1980年 | 10篇 |
1978年 | 8篇 |
1977年 | 7篇 |
1976年 | 8篇 |
1974年 | 14篇 |
1969年 | 5篇 |
排序方式: 共有7453条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
11.
Lionel Fontagné Michael Freudenberg Guillaume Gaulier 《Review of World Economics》2006,142(3):459-475
We provide a systematic decomposition of world trade using harmonized bilateral flows at the most available detail (some 5,000
product categories), into three trade types: inter-industry, intra-industry in horizontally and in vertically differentiated
products. The analysis is diachronic and considers country pairs such as France-Germany, United States-China, Malaysia-Singapore,
or India-Nigeria.
We show that the increase in IIT at the world level is due to two-way trade of vertically differentiated products. We find
France and Germany having the highest share of IIT in their bilateral trade among all country pairs in the world. In value
terms, the most important bilateral IIT is between the United States and Canada. Recently, specialization according to the
classical theories of international trade (inter-industry trade), has recovered, due to the increasing participation of emerging
economies in world trade.
JEL no. F14, F15 相似文献
12.
Juncal Cunado Luis A. Gil-Alana Fernando Pérez de Gracia 《Review of World Economics》2006,142(1):67-91
We examine the real convergence hypothesis for 14 OECD countries looking at the fractional order of integration of the differences
of real GDP per capita in these countries with respect to the United States. Using parametric procedures, the results vary
depending on how we specify the I(0) disturbances. If they are white noise, convergence is achieved for Canada and Australia,
and with autocorrelated disturbances, this hypothesis is satisfied for France and the Netherlands. However, allowing for a
break at World War II, evidence of convergence is obtained for all countries.
JEL no. C32, O41 相似文献
13.
14.
Clémence Berson 《De Economist》2018,166(4):455-476
The French labor market is segmented between permanent and temporary workers. The second category has difficulty in getting an open-ended contract. This paper aims at depicting workers on short-term contracts and shows the consequences on their professional career are negative and significant. A large part of the wage gap between permanent and temporary workers remains unexplained by observable characteristics. They receive less on-the-job training and their likelihood of obtaining a stable job is lower than 30% after 1 year and a half. They have also a higher probability of being the adjustment variable in case of an economic negative shock. These different findings show the importance of using public policies to encourage transitions from fixed-term to permanent employment and reducing labor-market duality. 相似文献
15.
Florentino Felgueroso José-Ignacio García-Pérez Marcel Jansen David Troncoso-Ponce 《De Economist》2018,166(4):503-534
Until the outbreak of the recent economic and financial crisis, Spain was leading the ranking of countries with the largest share of temporary employees. During the crisis this share has fallen to its lowest level in decades, but this does not mean that working conditions in Spain have improved. The flow of new temporary contracts is larger than ever before. A particularly striking feature is the steep growth in the volume of fixed-duration contracts lasting less than a week or a month. We document these trends and analyse how this phenomenon has affected the transition from temporary to permanent employment. 相似文献
16.
The economic convergence criteria adopted in the Maastricht Treaty and the fiscal discipline of the Stability and Growth Pact enforced nominal convergence, leaving aside real convergence indicators. In this paper, we use cluster analysis to examine the convergence patterns of income inequality, absolute redistribution (a measure of governments’ effectiveness in correcting for inequality) and unemployment. The expected outcome after years of economic integration was, ex-ante, convergence to a single cluster. Our results, however, uncover a variety of groups, implying that economic integration has not led to real economic convergence. Moreover, the existence of different patterns suggests: (i) that traditional classifications (Anglo-Saxon, Continental European, European Periphery, and Nordic models) remain broadly valid; (ii) that there is no unemployment-inequality trade-off to be exploited in terms of economic policy; and (iii) that the redistributive capacity of governments plays a pivotal role in coping with inequality without negative effects in terms of unemployment. 相似文献
17.
Umut Kılınç 《Open Economies Review》2018,29(5):953-980
Empirical evidence suggests that exporter firms tend to charge higher markups than non-exporters due to trade barriers. The exporters’ markup premium, however, may disappear in a special case, namely when the home country is small relative to its trade partners and trade barriers are low. This can be because competition is more intense in the large export destination than in the small home country, so that firms are able to set higher markups for locally sold products but not for exports. This paper provides empirical evidence on the validity of this special case by estimating markups for firms in Luxembourg who generally export to larger countries. The estimated negative markup premium for exporters has important implications for the productivity measurement. In a sufficiently small open economy, exporters’ productivity may be biased downward, when the firm-level markup variation is not controlled for in the productivity estimation. The bias in the productivity estimates further leads to the inaccurate conclusion that openness to international trade lowers allocative efficiency. 相似文献
18.
19.
ABSTRACTMore than ten years after the global financial crisis, what has happened to the ‘too-big-to-fail’ (TBTF) banks whose reckless behavior was among its preconditions, but which received public support and guarantees in the midst of that crisis? Insofar as this too-big-to-fail status helped create the crisis and then imposed costs on the rest of society, we would expect these banks to have shrunk. We investigate the evolution of 31 global-TBTF banks and find that their overall size has hardly recorded any substantial change. However, there is no sense of urgency in the flourishing post-crisis literature on TBTF banks about the need to contain their size; the prevalent view therein is that if properly regulated, the risks that arise from a financial system dominated by TBTF banks are manageable. This view rests on the same overly narrow theoretical underpinnings whose flaws were exposed in the crisis. We argue that too-big-to-fail banking is embedded in a set of self-reinforcing policies—consolidation, balance-sheet support through quantitative easing, favorable regulations, bank lobbying, and geo-economic and geo-political considerations—which explain why these banks have not shrunk and why they remain a threat to financial stability, well after the lessons of the crisis should have been learned. 相似文献
20.