首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   14526篇
  免费   401篇
财政金融   3036篇
工业经济   1096篇
计划管理   2333篇
经济学   3111篇
综合类   200篇
运输经济   106篇
旅游经济   227篇
贸易经济   2314篇
农业经济   641篇
经济概况   1848篇
信息产业经济   2篇
邮电经济   13篇
  2023年   76篇
  2021年   93篇
  2020年   207篇
  2019年   264篇
  2018年   342篇
  2017年   346篇
  2016年   319篇
  2015年   217篇
  2014年   341篇
  2013年   1617篇
  2012年   421篇
  2011年   499篇
  2010年   459篇
  2009年   473篇
  2008年   438篇
  2007年   377篇
  2006年   368篇
  2005年   301篇
  2004年   278篇
  2003年   280篇
  2002年   280篇
  2001年   287篇
  2000年   295篇
  1999年   296篇
  1998年   301篇
  1997年   265篇
  1996年   222篇
  1995年   220篇
  1994年   237篇
  1993年   241篇
  1992年   265篇
  1991年   253篇
  1990年   201篇
  1989年   182篇
  1988年   165篇
  1987年   162篇
  1986年   168篇
  1985年   237篇
  1984年   254篇
  1983年   245篇
  1982年   212篇
  1981年   195篇
  1980年   168篇
  1979年   167篇
  1978年   156篇
  1977年   135篇
  1976年   123篇
  1975年   139篇
  1974年   99篇
  1973年   100篇
排序方式: 共有10000条查询结果,搜索用时 703 毫秒
991.
992.
993.
994.
Tracing the income patterns of individual farm operators whose major source of income is generally derived from farming indicates that off-farm income is becoming an increasingly important income component. The relative importance of off-farm income has nearly quadrupled during the last 20 years, rising from about 10 percent of total income to about 37 percent of total income. Most of this off-farm income can be traced to wages and salaries. These fractions are heavily dependent upon relative income levels. In 1970, very low income farmers posted an aggregate net farm loss whereas the $15,000 - $20,000 class secured about three-quarters of their total income from farm sources. In this same year, wages and salaries were generally the prime off-farm income source for farmers with an assessed income of less than $20,000. Dividends and interest were more important to farmers with an income in excess of $20,000. These differences are faithfully reflected in the regional compilations. As a percent of total income, off-farm income ranged from 41 percent in Ontario to about 29 percent in Quebec. The composition of off-farm sources also varies considerably between regions. In 1970 the income position of taxable unincorporated farm operators (who relied on the farm for their major source of income) remained relatively unfavorable. These farmers still had one of the lowest average incomes of any major occupational class in Canada, with an income distribution which was relatively equally distributed between income classes and not unlike that of the national average. These assessed income statistics, of course, are not necessarily indicative of the welfare position of the respective occupational classes. The calculations conducted are simply illustrative of how income tax statistics can be utilized to facilitate our understanding of the income structure in primary agriculture today. The exercise simply underlines the observation that: The fact that there are conceptual differences between income tax data and other data sources should not detract from the usefulness of the income tax data …. Income tax statistics can stand as an independent data source for the analysis of a variety of issues [13]. For many purposes the tax definition of a farm operator may be more operational than the concept of a farmer as defined in the Census of Agriculture. We might profit considerably from further analyses which attempt to disaggregate Census farms into more homogeneous farm-types using the tax statistics available.  相似文献   
995.
996.
人素质教育是素质教育的关键所在。加强人素质教育是实现教育目标的要求,是时代发展的趋势。进行人素质教育是一个系统工程,要全面安排,科学管理。  相似文献   
997.
998.
999.
1000.
The dynamics of export market exit and firm closure have found limited attention in the new heterogeneous-firms trade literature. In fact, several of the predictions on firm survival and exit stemming from this new class of models are at odds with the stylized facts. Empirically, higher productivity firms survive longer, most firm closures are young firms, higher productivity exporters are more likely to continue to export compared to less productive exporters and market exits as well as firm closures are typically preceded by periods of contracting market shares. The present paper shows that the simple inclusion of exogenous economy wide technological progress into the standard Melitz (2003) model generates a tractable dynamic framework that generates endogenous exit decisions of firms in line with the stylized facts. Furthermore, we derive the effects of faster technological progress and trade liberalization on export market exit and firm closure.  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号