首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   1376篇
  免费   49篇
财政金融   234篇
工业经济   98篇
计划管理   292篇
经济学   219篇
综合类   6篇
运输经济   36篇
旅游经济   80篇
贸易经济   272篇
农业经济   23篇
经济概况   165篇
  2023年   5篇
  2022年   3篇
  2021年   8篇
  2020年   28篇
  2019年   38篇
  2018年   41篇
  2017年   36篇
  2016年   36篇
  2015年   31篇
  2014年   52篇
  2013年   250篇
  2012年   51篇
  2011年   68篇
  2010年   44篇
  2009年   47篇
  2008年   57篇
  2007年   44篇
  2006年   40篇
  2005年   56篇
  2004年   40篇
  2003年   42篇
  2002年   38篇
  2001年   32篇
  2000年   37篇
  1999年   25篇
  1998年   35篇
  1997年   30篇
  1996年   27篇
  1995年   14篇
  1994年   21篇
  1993年   12篇
  1992年   6篇
  1991年   13篇
  1990年   15篇
  1989年   13篇
  1988年   9篇
  1987年   11篇
  1986年   9篇
  1985年   8篇
  1984年   14篇
  1983年   8篇
  1982年   5篇
  1981年   3篇
  1980年   3篇
  1979年   3篇
  1978年   4篇
  1977年   2篇
  1976年   5篇
  1971年   1篇
  1967年   1篇
排序方式: 共有1425条查询结果,搜索用时 0 毫秒
961.
Collective-action problems arise in a variety of situations.Open-source software is a recent and important example. Copyrightrestrictions on open-source projects stipulate that any usermay modify the software so long as any resulting innovationis freely available to all. In economic parlance, the innovationis a public good. The economic theory of public-good provisionraises a number of important questions. Who contributes to sucha project, and who free rides? How might a social planner exploitthe interdependence of project components to encourage contributions?Under what conditions will such actions result in successfulprovision? Using a simple game-theoretic framework and recentresults from the study of equilibrium selection, we attemptto answer these questions. Under reasonable assumptions of asymmetryand less than complete information, the most efficient providerswill contribute. Contributions can be elicited by ‘integrating’the provision process when providers are sufficiently optimisticabout the success of the project. Otherwise, the social plannermay be better off ‘separating’ the components sothat individual contributions are independent of each other.The analysis yields recommendations for the leaders of open-sourceprojects and other similar collective-action problems.  相似文献   
962.
Darius et al. (2007) and Nolan & Temple Lang (2007) give examples of virtual environments that can, for specific purposes, substitute for the real world. We are in the early stages of developments that could revolutionize statistics education by making it possible to capture efficiently important aspects of the thinking and practice of professional statisticians previously learned only from long years of experience. The ability of virtual environments to automate processes provides a potent weapon for tackling the tyranny that Time exercises over such modes of learning. We discuss the many new possibilities that are opened up by virtual environments together with cognitive and pedagogical imperatives to be addressed to ensure that environments actually do teach the lessons they were designed to teach. We echo Nolan and Temple Lang's call for the development of environments to be modular and open source. Taking the R‐project as a model, this can lead to a growing repository of building blocks that make the construction of future environments less costly, thus facilitating the realization of more and more ambitious conceptions.  相似文献   
963.
This paper develops several indicators to measure the extent and depth of rules governing international migration. It is set in the context of moves towards further liberalisation of services trade and associated labour mobility (Mode 4) under GATS and related regional trading arrangements. Ten Southeast Asian countries at various stages of economic development are examined as a case study, with special reference to health care and information technology. These sectors are priority sectors for regional cooperation in services trade in ASEAN, but were expected to represent opposite extremes in terms of the regulation of migration. The study finds that the more advanced countries tend to have more liberal regimes for international movements of skilled manpower, although there were smaller differences regarding general visa and work permit arrangements. Generic restrictions on mobility were related to trade policies, as well as to direct barriers (often country‐specific) to migration. They included minimum salary requirement, levies on foreign workers, economic needs tests, and limitations related to language, education and job experience. Controls were more extensive in the health care sector, related to social considerations as well as professional organisational interests.  相似文献   
964.
965.
966.
967.
968.
969.
970.
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号