首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   221篇
  免费   1篇
财政金融   93篇
工业经济   9篇
计划管理   46篇
经济学   28篇
综合类   1篇
旅游经济   2篇
贸易经济   27篇
农业经济   2篇
经济概况   14篇
  2023年   4篇
  2021年   2篇
  2020年   15篇
  2019年   7篇
  2018年   2篇
  2017年   7篇
  2014年   2篇
  2013年   10篇
  2012年   2篇
  2011年   2篇
  2010年   7篇
  2009年   4篇
  2008年   8篇
  2007年   10篇
  2006年   2篇
  2005年   5篇
  2004年   3篇
  2003年   6篇
  2002年   4篇
  2001年   8篇
  2000年   8篇
  1999年   8篇
  1998年   4篇
  1997年   7篇
  1996年   4篇
  1995年   6篇
  1994年   10篇
  1993年   5篇
  1992年   4篇
  1991年   3篇
  1990年   3篇
  1989年   3篇
  1988年   3篇
  1987年   1篇
  1985年   12篇
  1984年   9篇
  1983年   3篇
  1982年   3篇
  1981年   2篇
  1980年   3篇
  1979年   1篇
  1978年   1篇
  1977年   3篇
  1976年   2篇
  1975年   4篇
排序方式: 共有222条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
61.
The retail park is one of the most ubiquitous and significant forms of off-centre retailing in the UK. Originally designed as low-cost accommodation for 'bulky goods', retail parks now include high-rent 'fashion parks' which are eagerly sought by institutional investors for long-term ownership. This paper explains why retail-park ownership, originating in the early 1980s in one-off schemes by locally based property developers, has become the province of major property companies, financial institutions, and asset managers. Growth in rents and capital values has been fuelled by increasing institutional investment, and by fears of a growing scarcity of high-quality developments because of town-planning restrictions. This pressure is now leading to attempts to realize the full capital value of older developments, through processes of 'active management' by the new breed of retail-park owners. In turn, this is leading to increasingly rapid changes of retail occupiers, involving in some cases the expulsion of the original 'bulky goods' retailers for whom retail parks were created. A parallel with the 'Wheel of Retailing' model of institutional change is suggested.  相似文献   
62.
63.
64.
65.
The value of exchange traded fund (ETF) assets has increased from $66 billion in 2000 to almost a trillion dollars in 2010. We use this massive expansion in ETF assets to study what drives ETF flows. Using a data set of over 500 ETFs from 2001 to 2010, we show that ETF investors chase returns in the same way as mutual fund investors. While there is an active debate about whether return chasing by mutual fund investors represents the pursuit of superior talent, the existence of return chasing in this passively managed environment should not represent a search for skilled managers. We also show that ETF flows increase following high volume, small spreads, and high price/net asset value ratios. Finally, we find little evidence of superior market timing in ETF flows. Our results suggest that return chasing in both mutual funds and ETFs is more likely the result of naïve extrapolation bias on the part of investors that has contributed to the growth of the ETF industry.  相似文献   
66.
67.
68.
The authors provide a fundamental rethinking of how corporations should evaluate various kinds of risks and risk management solutions—a rethinking that leads to a major shift in British Petroleum's approach to insuring property and casualty losses, product liability suits, and other insurable events. Conventional corporate practice—and until the early 1990s (when this article was written) the longstanding policy of BP and most large oil companies—was to insure against large losses while self‐insuring against smaller ones. In this article, the authors explain why BP has chosen to go against the conventional wisdom and instead buy insurance for mainly smaller losses while self‐insuring larger ones. The BP decision came down to factors affecting the market supply of insurance as well as the corporate demand for it. On the demand side, the authors demonstrate that the primary source of demand for insurance by large public companies is not, as standard insurance textbooks assume, to transfer risk away from the corporation's owners. Because corporate stockholders and bondholders effectively manage the effects of such risks by diversifying their own portfolios, the corporate demand for insurance in BP's case stems from the insurers' comparative advantage in evaluating and monitoring BP's smaller risks and in processing claims. On the supply side, the authors explain why the capacity of insurance companies and markets to underwrite very large or highly specialized exposures—when compared to the industry expertise and financial resources of companies like BP—is quite limited, and likely to remain so. Since premiums would be experience‐rated and prior years' losses simply rolled into the following years' premiums, there would be no effective transfer of risk, and so no gain to BP from buying insurance.  相似文献   
69.
This paper compares the characteristics of derivatives users and non-users, using data from U.S. savings associations during 1993–1994. Unlike prior studies, the data used in this analysis are market values of assets and liabilities. Market values were obtained from the base case (no interest rate change) in the Office of Thrift Supervision's (OTS) Net Portfolio Value Model. This model calculates the value of all of a thrift's positions to calculate the value at risk. We determine the consistency of theories of derivatives use with the characteristics of derivatives users.  相似文献   
70.
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号