全文获取类型
收费全文 | 173篇 |
免费 | 6篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 65篇 |
工业经济 | 29篇 |
计划管理 | 12篇 |
经济学 | 42篇 |
贸易经济 | 8篇 |
农业经济 | 3篇 |
经济概况 | 20篇 |
出版年
2024年 | 1篇 |
2023年 | 5篇 |
2021年 | 1篇 |
2020年 | 6篇 |
2019年 | 2篇 |
2018年 | 3篇 |
2017年 | 3篇 |
2016年 | 1篇 |
2015年 | 1篇 |
2014年 | 5篇 |
2013年 | 4篇 |
2012年 | 6篇 |
2011年 | 11篇 |
2010年 | 7篇 |
2009年 | 7篇 |
2008年 | 10篇 |
2007年 | 10篇 |
2006年 | 7篇 |
2005年 | 4篇 |
2004年 | 1篇 |
2001年 | 1篇 |
1999年 | 2篇 |
1998年 | 1篇 |
1997年 | 11篇 |
1995年 | 4篇 |
1994年 | 8篇 |
1993年 | 5篇 |
1992年 | 2篇 |
1991年 | 4篇 |
1990年 | 5篇 |
1989年 | 5篇 |
1988年 | 4篇 |
1987年 | 4篇 |
1986年 | 1篇 |
1985年 | 4篇 |
1984年 | 2篇 |
1982年 | 6篇 |
1981年 | 2篇 |
1980年 | 4篇 |
1979年 | 1篇 |
1978年 | 1篇 |
1977年 | 1篇 |
1976年 | 1篇 |
1972年 | 1篇 |
1971年 | 1篇 |
1970年 | 1篇 |
1967年 | 1篇 |
1958年 | 1篇 |
排序方式: 共有179条查询结果,搜索用时 0 毫秒
11.
DANIEL FINN 《American journal of economics and sociology》2012,71(4):874-885
In Catholic Social Thought, work is at the center of issues related to morality and economic life. It is simultaneously objective and subjective. Workers are the real agents of production, and therefore labor should have priority over capital. The able‐bodied have a moral obligation to work to obtain the things they need, but everyone has a claim on the basic necessities of life. Hence the property claims of the well‐to‐do are not to exclude the poor from what they need. The property‐right claim of stockholders depends on the firm serving work and the interests of workers. In unions, workers' natural right to form associations aligns with the right to participate in decisions affecting their lives. Numerous groups and organizations have some degree of complicity in workplace injustice and some degree of responsibility to address it. 相似文献
12.
A model of risk reduction is used to analyze personal bankruptcy rates. The model shows how state and federal laws can affect the quantity of resources that lenders devote to reducing the risk of making bad loans. Unanticipated events cause changes in bankruptcy rates because they alter the costs and benefits of bankruptcy to both creditors and debtors. Results of other studies are shown to be consistent with this model. Data for 1980 are then used to test the model. Asset exemption laws have a significant impact on bankruptcy rates that is consistent with the model. Unanticipated economic events are also found to have significant effects on bankruptcy rates. 相似文献
13.
14.
Abstract. This paper extends the growing literature on factors affecting cross-sectional and intertemporal variation in earnings response coefficients. It tests the empirical implications of recent theoretical work by Choi and Salamon (1989) and Holthausen and Verrecchia (1988), who model the degree of price adjustment associated with earnings announcements as a function of the amount of noise or garbling in the accounting earnings signal relative to valuation-relevant cash flows or dividends. The particular earnings measurements considered relate to U.S. multinational companies and to the differences in income determination under Statement of Financial Accounting Standards (SFAS) No. 8 and SFAS No. 52. The study finds a modestly smaller relative price adjustment for a given amount of unexpected earnings for multinational firms than for nonmultinationals during the SFAS No. 8 period. This finding is consistent with multinationals producing “noisier” earnings signals during this time period. However, several indirect measures suggest that there was greater prior probability uncertainty associated with the future cash flows or dividends of the nonmultinational sample. Accordingly, this cannot be ruled out as a competing explanation for the observed differences in the market's response to earnings signals during the SFAS No. 8 period. Following the implementation of SFAS No. 52, the earnings response coefficient increased substantively for firms whose accounting for translation gains or losses was most affected by this standard. These results suggest that the earnings measurements produced under SFAS No. 52 were perceived by market participants to be of higher quality (less noisy) than those produced under SFAS No. 8. The framework and analysis in this paper hold promise for investigating the relative informativeness of earnings signals produced under alternative income determination rules. Résumé. Les auteurs apportent leur contribution personnelle aux publications de plus en plus nombreuses portant sur les facteurs qui touchent la variation transversale et temporelle des coefficients de réaction aux bénéfices. Ils vérifient les conséquences empiriques des travaux théoriques récents de Choi et Salamon (1989) et de Holthausen et Verrecchia (1988), qui modélisent le degré d'ajustement du cours des valeurs associé aux annonces de bénéfices comme étant fonction de la quantité de parasites ou de l'importance du brouillage dans le signal que constituent des bénéfices comptables par rapport aux flux monétaires ou aux dividendes pertinents à l'évaluation. Les mesures particulières des bénéfices auxquelles s'intéressent les auteurs sont celles de multinationales des États-Unis et font état de la variation des bénéfices, selon qu'ils sont évalués conformément au SFAS no 8 ou au SFAS no 52. Pour un montant donné de bénéfices inattendus, les auteurs constatent un ajustement relatif du cours des valeurs légèrement plus faible dans le cas des multinationales que dans celui des entreprises d'envergure plus modeste, au cours de la période d'application du SFAS no 8. Cette constatation est conforme à l'hypothèse voulant que les multinationales aient produit des indicateurs de bénéfices plus « brouillés » au cours de cette période. Toutefois, plusieurs mesures indirectes donnent à penser qu'il existait une incertitude plus grande quant à la probabilité a priori des flux monétaires ou des dividendes futurs dans l'échantillon des entreprises d'envergure plus modeste. Les auteurs ne peuvent donc écarter cette hypothèse à titre d'explication concurrente des différences observées dans la réaction du marché aux indicateurs de bénéfices, au cours de la période d'application du SFAS no 8. À la suite de l'instauration du SFAS no 52, le coefficient de réaction aux bénéfices a sensiblement augmenté dans le cas des entreprises dont la méthode comptable relative à la conversion des gains et des pertes était davantage touchée par cette norme. Ces résultats laissent croire que les mesures des bénéfices conformes au SFAS no 52 ont été perçues par les intéressés comme étant de plus grande qualité (c'est-à-dire moins brouillées) que les mesures conformes au SFAS no 8. Le cadre de référence et l'analyse contenus dans cet article sont prometteurs pour l'analyse de la qualité relative de l'information livrée par les indicateurs de bénéfices conformes à d'autres règles d'évaluation des bénéfices. 相似文献
15.
DANIEL B. THORNTON 《Contemporary Accounting Research》1988,5(1):343-370
Abstract. This paper explores relationships between capital values in use (market values, which include “goodwill”, or abnormal growth opportunities) and capital replacement costs for the 52 publicly traded Canadian firms that disclosed such data in 1983 and 1984. Tobin's Q is one at the margin and regresses toward one over time, as predicted by economic theory, but differs across industries: Q-ratios of manufacturers average one; those of resource firms exceed one, probably reflecting Ricardian rents; those of utilities are less than one, possibly due to regulatory constraints. Q-ratios based on replacement cost data cannot be accurately estimated from historic cost accounting data. Replacement cost data may contain random measurement error but evidently not bias. Thus the data may be especially useful for assessing the performance of portfolios of firms, in which random error will be diversified away. Cross sectional regression analyses indicate that Canadian accounting procedures overstate shareholders' equity and understate bondholders' equity in replacement costs. Thus some financial ratios based on replacement cost data (e.g., leverage) are biased. Evidence on how deferred taxes are reflected in security prices is ambiguous. Implications of the findings for accounting standard setters, researchers and users of financial statements are discussed. Résumé. L'auteur explore les relations entre les valeurs en capital utilisées (les valeurs marchandes comprenant l'«achalandage» ou les possibilités de croissance inusitées) et les coûts de remplacement de capital pour les 52 entreprises canadiennes inscrites à la bourse qui ont livré ce genre de données en 1983 et 1984. L'indice Q de Tobin est de un à la marge et régresse vers un dans le temps, comme le prévoit la théorie économique, mais il diffère selon les secteurs: les indices Q des entreprises manufacturières sont de un en moyenne; ceux des entreprises d'extraction de ressources excèdent un, ce qui reflète probablement les rentes ricardiennes; et ceux des services pubics sont inférieurs à un, possiblement en raison des contraintes de la réglementation. Les indices Q basés sur les données relatives au coût de remplacement ne peuvent être estimés avec exactitude à partir des données comptables relatives aux coûts d'origine. Les données relatives au coût de remplacement peuvent contenir une erreur de mesure aléatoire mais, bien sûr, aucun biais. Ces données peuvent donc être particulièrement utiles dans l'évaluation du rendement des portefeuilles des sociétés, dans laquelle l'erreur aléatoire sera diluée. Les analyses de régression intersectorielles révèlent que les procédés comptables canadiens surestiment l'avoir des actionnaires et sous-estiment l'avoir des détenteurs d'obligations en coûts de remplacement. Par conséquent, certains ratios financiers basés sur les données relatives au coût de remplacement (l'effet de levier financier par exemple) sont biaisés. La façon dont les impôts reportés sont reflétés dans le prix des titres est ambiguë. L'auteur traite des conséquences des résultats de cette étude pour les resposables de l'établissement des normes comptables, les chercheurs et les utilisateurs des états financiers. 相似文献
16.
17.
Abstract. This article presents an explanation of the reasons that managers might elect to change accounting methods. Facing adversity with a nontrivial probability of technical default on the debt covenants, the manager is motivated to effect an income-increasing accounting change to circumvent a technical default. Under rational expectations, if investors do not have any prior information about the firm's adversity, the market reaction on an accounting change announcement is predicted to be negative. We postulate that the market impact on the date of change announcement is negatively correlated with the amount of information the investors may have. A sample of 77 firms was selected to test the economic arguments. Investors' reaction to the accounting change was tested by abnormal returns on dates of announcement. Cross-sectional tests associate the investors' reaction with their prior information about the financial status of the sample firms. On the date of the change announcement, the sample firms did not experience a statistically significant negative market reaction. However, in a cross-sectional analysis, the market impact parameter was found to be significantly correlated in a negative manner with the prior information proxy variable. 相似文献
18.
19.
In the setting of a one‐dimensional legislative bargaining game, we characterize qualified majority rules maximizing social surplus, that is, the sum of individual benefits. The simple majority rule maximizes social surplus when individual utilities are tent‐shaped. When the utilities are strictly concave, the surplus maximizing rule is a strict supermajority. 相似文献
20.
Abstract. The decision to disclose information concerning a firm's environmental liabilities is modeled as a sequential game involving the firm, a capital market, and outside stakeholders who can impose proprietary (political) costs on the firm. A partial disclosure equilibrium is derived in which firms reveal information strategically, maximizing the share-value net of expected political costs. Inherent uncertainty regarding the existence and size of the liabilities creates a setting where outsiders are uncertain if management is informed about these liabilities, so firms can plausibly withhold “bad news”, that is, they do not disclose liabilities that exceed a threshold level. Three novel hypotheses are that a firm is more likely to disclose as (1) its pollution propensity increases, (2) outsiders' knowledge of its environmental liabilities increases, and (3) the risk of incurring proprietary costs decreases. Empirical support is found for the hypotheses, based on the accounting disclosures made by sample firms selected from the records of the Ontario Ministry of the Environment and Energy. Improved accounting and auditing standards for environmental disclosure would build on at least three implications of the study:
- 1 To the extent that inherent uncertainty leaves managers with discretion as to what to disclose, the partial disclosure equilibrium result suggests that not all firms will comply with disclosure standards.
- 2 Publishing broad environmental performance indicators for companies in nonaccounting outlets would increase public awareness of a manager's private information endowment, making voluntary accounting disclosures of the liabilities more likely.
- 3 If a significant decline in stakeholder tolerance of pollution occurs, the expected proprietary costs of disclosing increase, and companies become less likely to disclose.