全文获取类型
收费全文 | 492篇 |
免费 | 9篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 56篇 |
工业经济 | 14篇 |
计划管理 | 74篇 |
经济学 | 165篇 |
运输经济 | 1篇 |
旅游经济 | 3篇 |
贸易经济 | 140篇 |
经济概况 | 38篇 |
邮电经济 | 10篇 |
出版年
2021年 | 5篇 |
2019年 | 6篇 |
2018年 | 13篇 |
2017年 | 10篇 |
2016年 | 14篇 |
2015年 | 14篇 |
2014年 | 19篇 |
2013年 | 29篇 |
2012年 | 21篇 |
2011年 | 19篇 |
2010年 | 16篇 |
2009年 | 15篇 |
2008年 | 15篇 |
2007年 | 11篇 |
2006年 | 17篇 |
2004年 | 11篇 |
2003年 | 8篇 |
2002年 | 8篇 |
2001年 | 12篇 |
2000年 | 7篇 |
1999年 | 10篇 |
1998年 | 9篇 |
1997年 | 5篇 |
1996年 | 5篇 |
1995年 | 4篇 |
1994年 | 4篇 |
1993年 | 6篇 |
1992年 | 5篇 |
1991年 | 5篇 |
1990年 | 10篇 |
1989年 | 4篇 |
1988年 | 4篇 |
1987年 | 6篇 |
1986年 | 9篇 |
1985年 | 9篇 |
1983年 | 4篇 |
1982年 | 4篇 |
1981年 | 11篇 |
1980年 | 4篇 |
1979年 | 9篇 |
1978年 | 8篇 |
1977年 | 10篇 |
1976年 | 9篇 |
1975年 | 4篇 |
1970年 | 7篇 |
1960年 | 3篇 |
1958年 | 4篇 |
1957年 | 4篇 |
1956年 | 3篇 |
1930年 | 3篇 |
排序方式: 共有501条查询结果,搜索用时 11 毫秒
121.
In this paper we study whether majority voting equilibria exist when preferences over public policies are not single peaked. The government levies a proportional income tax. Tax revenue is used to finance a uniform lump-sum transfer and public education. Individuals vote on the composition of the government budget. We show that the single-crossing property cannot be invoked to establish existence of a majority voting equilibrium. In a simple parametric example we find that cycles are pervasive. 相似文献
122.
Gerhard Thury 《Empirica》1981,8(1):3-24
Summary The use of ARIMA models in applied economic forecasting has become more and more popular in recent years. In order to secure a good forecasting performance of these models, great care should be spent on the correct identification and the efficient estimation of models of this type.The present paper deals with problems often encountered in applied time series analysis. When fitting an ARIMA model to an observed macroeconomic time series, it might be detected that several models seem to represent this series equally well. The problem here is how to discriminate between alternative ARIMA model specifications representing the same macroeconomic time series.In the first part of the paperthe theoretical concepts, used in the identification and estimation of an ARIMA model, are briefly reviewed. In the second part, these techniques are then applied in a case-study in order to obtain ARIMA models for private consumer expenditure and disposable personal income.
I would like to thankJohannes Ledolter from the University of Iowa for his very helpful comments on an earlier draft of this paper. 相似文献
Zusammenfassung Die vorliegende Arbeit beschäftigt sich mit einigen Problemen der angewandten Zeitreihen-analyse. Beim Versuch, ein ARIMA-Modell für beobachtete makroökonomische Zeitreihen zu schätzen, entdeckt man bisweilen, daß mehrere Modelle die Zeitreihe gleich gut zu repräsentieren scheinen. Hier stellt sich dann die Frage, ob es verläßliche Kriterien gibt, die eine Auswahl aus alternativen Modellansätzen gestatten. Im ersten Teil der Arbeit werden kurz die Konzepte, die für die Identifikation und Schätzung von ARIMA-Modellen zur Verfügung stehen, dargestellt. Der zweite Teil stellt eine Fallstudie dar, in der ARIMA-Modelle für den privaten Konsum und das verfügbare persönliche Einkommen entwickelt werden.
I would like to thankJohannes Ledolter from the University of Iowa for his very helpful comments on an earlier draft of this paper. 相似文献
123.
Summary This paper examines two aspects of equilibrium — and stability concepts, which go beyond the traditional analyses. Firstly the speed by which a systems returns to the equilibrium position after an initial disturbance and, secondly, the introduction of stochastic elements in the analysis of stability. Both aspects are presented against the background of a simple model of the Austrian economy.It is known that a system of difference equations is stable if the greatest sigenvalue is smaller than one. In trying to estimate confidence intervals it can be shown that an evaluation according to deterministic criteria alone can indeed be misleading, even though the probability of an instable solution is small in the model under examiniation.The speed, by which a system returns to the equilibrium position after an initial disturbance, is measured by the half-life-period. This is the time it takes for the effects of the initial disturbance to be reduced to half their original values. In the model under examination the half-line amounts to one year (real solution) or two years (complex solution) respectively. If we take the stochastic nature of the eigenvalues into consideration, we get, for the 95% level of significance, figures of 3 months to 6 years in the real case. The large spread results from the fact that the half-life-concept is very sensitive even towards minor changes in the eigenvalues.This paper shows that the conventional methods of estimation of coefficients in stability-analyses are not sufficiently accurate. 相似文献
124.
Gerhard Tutz 《Quality and Quantity》1995,29(4):405-420
Two principle approaches to the modelling of competing risks in discrete time are considered. In the first approach which is based on the separation between failure and cause specific response only the causes of failure are considered as ordered. The second approach which is based on the conditional response given interval [a t-1,ar) is reached allows for an ordering of causes of failureand the category ‘no failure’. The latter approach is shown to be more general. It is shown that the considered competing risks models may be estimated within the framework of generalized linear models. A data set concerning duration of unemployment illustrates the approaches. 相似文献
125.
In the business world one of the key drivers to reduce uncertainty is trust. It is based on an empirical study (Kano-analysis, 60% return rate) and identifies relevant factors of a trustful communication in long-term business relationships between organizations. Three types of factors can be identified: Must-be factors are a prerequisite of any relation and have a fundamental character in long-term relationships. The customers expect such factors to be an unquestionable part of any business relation (e.g. honesty). While attractive factors always boost the stability of trust in the relation (e.g. sympathy), one-dimensional factors not only stabilize trust if implemented, but can also deteriorate the relation if ignored (e.g. timeliness). 相似文献
126.
Editorial Announcement 总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1
At the 相似文献
127.
This paper shows that news shocks amplify macroeconomic volatility in any purely forward-looking model, whereas results are ambiguous when including a backward-looking component. We also investigate numerically the volatility effects of news shocks within the Smets and Wouters (2003) model. 相似文献
128.
129.
Summary. We extend the model from Tornell and Velasco [13] and Tornell and Lane [12] by adding three features: (i) extracting the common property asset involves a private appropriation cost, (ii) agents derive utility from wealth as well as from consumption, and (iii) agents can be heterogeneous. We show that both an increase in the appropriation cost and, when appropriation costs vary across agents, an increase in the degree of heterogeneity of these costs reduce the growth rate of the public capital stock. We also show that, in the interior equilibrium, the private asset can have either a lower or a higher money rate of return than the common property asset.Received: 22 June 2004, Revised: 20 April 2005, JEL Classification Numbers:
C73, O40.This research is supported by SSHRC, FQRSC, and the Austrian Science Fund (FWF). Thanks are due to Hassan Benchekroun, Parkash Chander, Gerard Gaudet, Basant Kapur, Kim Long, Colin Rowat, Koji Shimomura, and an anonymous referee for comments and discussions. 相似文献
130.
Gerhard Tutz 《Revue internationale de statistique》2021,89(1):18-35
Appropriate modelling of Likert‐type items should account for the scale level and the specific role of the neutral middle category, which is present in most Likert‐type items that are in common use. Powerful hierarchical models that account for both aspects are proposed. To avoid biased estimates, the models separate the neutral category when modelling the effects of explanatory variables on the outcome. The main model that is propagated uses binary response models as building blocks in a hierarchical way. It has the advantage that it can be easily extended to include response style effects and non‐linear smooth effects of explanatory variables. By simple transformation of the data, available software for binary response variables can be used to fit the model. The proposed hierarchical model can be used to investigate the effects of covariates on single Likert‐type items and also for the analysis of a combination of items. For both cases, estimation tools are provided. The usefulness of the approach is illustrated by applying the methodology to a large data set. 相似文献