全文获取类型
收费全文 | 12463篇 |
免费 | 215篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 2189篇 |
工业经济 | 863篇 |
计划管理 | 2076篇 |
经济学 | 2658篇 |
综合类 | 94篇 |
运输经济 | 79篇 |
旅游经济 | 166篇 |
贸易经济 | 1909篇 |
农业经济 | 707篇 |
经济概况 | 1895篇 |
信息产业经济 | 1篇 |
邮电经济 | 41篇 |
出版年
2020年 | 114篇 |
2019年 | 175篇 |
2018年 | 268篇 |
2017年 | 242篇 |
2016年 | 243篇 |
2015年 | 153篇 |
2014年 | 261篇 |
2013年 | 1061篇 |
2012年 | 349篇 |
2011年 | 350篇 |
2010年 | 291篇 |
2009年 | 349篇 |
2008年 | 338篇 |
2007年 | 294篇 |
2006年 | 282篇 |
2005年 | 243篇 |
2004年 | 248篇 |
2003年 | 238篇 |
2002年 | 248篇 |
2001年 | 219篇 |
2000年 | 250篇 |
1999年 | 219篇 |
1998年 | 205篇 |
1997年 | 185篇 |
1996年 | 203篇 |
1995年 | 183篇 |
1994年 | 195篇 |
1993年 | 191篇 |
1992年 | 209篇 |
1991年 | 206篇 |
1990年 | 206篇 |
1989年 | 178篇 |
1988年 | 143篇 |
1987年 | 153篇 |
1986年 | 170篇 |
1985年 | 247篇 |
1984年 | 225篇 |
1983年 | 195篇 |
1982年 | 199篇 |
1981年 | 200篇 |
1980年 | 189篇 |
1979年 | 188篇 |
1978年 | 166篇 |
1977年 | 155篇 |
1976年 | 149篇 |
1975年 | 151篇 |
1974年 | 116篇 |
1973年 | 114篇 |
1972年 | 107篇 |
1971年 | 83篇 |
排序方式: 共有10000条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
131.
What are the limits of collective action? As James Buchanan famously worried, is it possible to empower the productive state without lapsing into the predatory state? This paper uses insights from F.A. Hayek to address problems of public goods and the role of the state. Hayek convincingly argued that no central planner has sufficient knowledge to run an economy. Yet Hayek also allowed for state provision of some goods beyond the prevention of coercion. The question, then, is whether Hayek’s safeguards offer a satisfactory response to Buchanan’s worry. This paper contends that Hayek violated his own conditions for permissible government activity. Nevertheless, he offers a serious research agenda for limiting state abuses. 相似文献
132.
133.
134.
The Economic Impact of SFAS NO. 157 总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1
Sak Bhamornsiri Robert E. Guinn Richard G. Schroeder 《International Advances in Economic Research》2010,16(1):65-79
Statement of Financial Accounting Standards No. 157, “Fair Value Measurements,” (SFAS 157) defines fair value, establishes
a three tiered framework for measuring fair value and expands the required disclosures about fair value measurements. The
objective of this study is to examine and evaluate the benefits of the information disclosed by SFAS 157. The results of our
study indicated that a large majority of the inputs are observable in that 93.5% of the sample financial assets and 93.1%
of the sample financial liabilities were measured by level 1 or 2 criteria. However, we found a mismatch between assets and
liabilities subject to the three tiers of fair value measurements. The companies in our sample disclosed $18.8 trillion in
total assets, with 51%, or $18.8 trillion in
total assets, with 51%, or 9.5 trillion reported at fair value. Whereas, sample company liabilities totaled 16.1 trillion with only16.1 trillion
with only 3.7 trillion or 23% reported at fair value. 相似文献
135.
Lynn M. Shore Beth G. Chung-Herrera Michelle A. Dean Karen Holcombe Ehrhart Don I. Jung Amy E. Randel Gangaram Singh 《Human Resource Management Review》2009,19(2):117-133
A great deal of research has focused on workforce diversity. Despite an increasing number of studies, few consistent conclusions have yet to be reached about the antecedents and outcomes of diversity. Likewise, research on different dimensions of diversity (e.g., age, race, gender, sexual orientation, disability, and culture) has mostly evolved independently. Therefore, the purpose of this review is to examine each of these dimensions of diversity to describe common themes across dimensions and to develop an integrative model of diversity. 相似文献
136.
Schneider LG 《Medical economics》2000,77(15):163-6, 169
137.
138.
Burning bluegrass seed stubble is an important production practice that, among other benefits, increases production and stand life of this perennial crop. Despite economic forecasts that higher production costs from the 1996 state ban on seed stubble burning would reduce Washington production by up to 30%, output in the years 1998–2005 was nearly two-thirds higher than in any previous eight-year period. This study seeks to explain why that paradoxical behavior occurred. This study puts forward and systematically tests several hypotheses. The only hypothesis with any support, innovation offsets, is examined by an assessment of contemporaneous innovations and by corroborative statistical evidence. 相似文献
139.
According to the traditional view, judgment is an event: You make a decision and then move on. Yet Tichy, of the University of Michigan's Ross School of Business, and Bennis, of the University of Southern California's Marshall School of Business, found that good leadership judgment occurs not in a single moment but throughout a process. From their research into the complex phenomenon of leadership judgment, the authors also found that most important judgment calls reside in one of three domains: people, strategy, and crisis. Understanding the essence of leadership judgment is crucial. A leader's calls determine an organization's success or failure and deliver the verdict on his or her career. The first phase of the judgment process is preparation--identifying and framing the issue that demands a decision and aligning and mobilizing key stakeholders. Second is the call itself, And third is acting on the call, learning and adjusting along the way. Good leaders use a "story line"--an articulation of a company's identity, direction, and values--to inform their actions throughout the judgment process. Boeing CEO Jim McNerney, for instance, focused on a story line of Boeing as a world-class competitor and ethical leader to make a judgment call that launched the company's recovery from a string of ethical crises. Good leaders also take advantage of "redo loops" throughout the process, reconsidering the parameters of the decision, relabeling the problem, and redefining the goal in a way that more and more people can accept. Procter & Gamble's A.G. Lafley and Best Buy's Brad Anderson have both used redo loops--in preparation and execution, respectively--to strengthen not only support for their calls but also the outcomes. 相似文献
140.
Randall G. Holcombe 《The Review of Austrian Economics》2009,22(4):301-313
Behavioral and experimental economics present challenges to the neoclassical theory of individual behavior, which is based on individuals making choices within the framework of utility functions that are assumed to have certain well-defined characteristics. Results in behavioral and experimental economics have shown that it is common for individual behavior to systematically deviate from the neoclassical axioms of utility maximization. Austrian economics is also based on axiomatic theories of utility maximization, but the assumptions underlying utility-maximizing behavior are much weaker in the Austrian approach. As a result, they have more solid behavioral foundations and are less subject to challenge by the empirical findings of behavioral and experimental economics. Neoclassical policy conclusions are often overly strong because of its behavioral foundations which are challenged by behavioral and experimental economics and are often misleading because of the comparative static nature of neoclassical welfare economics. For purposes of policy analysis, the Austrian approach provides better insights because of its more realistic behavioral foundations. 相似文献