全文获取类型
收费全文 | 632篇 |
免费 | 5篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 118篇 |
工业经济 | 63篇 |
计划管理 | 81篇 |
经济学 | 150篇 |
综合类 | 3篇 |
运输经济 | 8篇 |
旅游经济 | 17篇 |
贸易经济 | 118篇 |
农业经济 | 54篇 |
经济概况 | 25篇 |
出版年
2024年 | 7篇 |
2023年 | 13篇 |
2022年 | 4篇 |
2021年 | 9篇 |
2020年 | 30篇 |
2019年 | 29篇 |
2018年 | 41篇 |
2017年 | 33篇 |
2016年 | 28篇 |
2015年 | 19篇 |
2014年 | 29篇 |
2013年 | 71篇 |
2012年 | 38篇 |
2011年 | 32篇 |
2010年 | 26篇 |
2009年 | 30篇 |
2008年 | 26篇 |
2007年 | 25篇 |
2006年 | 17篇 |
2005年 | 14篇 |
2004年 | 21篇 |
2003年 | 16篇 |
2002年 | 13篇 |
2001年 | 15篇 |
2000年 | 7篇 |
1999年 | 9篇 |
1998年 | 11篇 |
1997年 | 2篇 |
1996年 | 5篇 |
1995年 | 6篇 |
1994年 | 5篇 |
1993年 | 2篇 |
1991年 | 1篇 |
1990年 | 1篇 |
1988年 | 1篇 |
1969年 | 1篇 |
排序方式: 共有637条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
61.
62.
Jason M. Bienenfeld Elizabeth R. Botkins Brian E. Roe Marvin T. Batte 《Agricultural Economics》2016,47(2):205-213
We investigate the value of a country of origin label (COOL) that separately identifies the geographic location of different stages in a food product's supply chain. We estimate the willingness‐to‐pay (WTP) of U.S. consumers for a packaged cereal product where the key grain ingredient may be grown in one country and processed in a second country (multicountry supply chain) and compare it to equivalent products that have both stages located in a single country. We find consumer WTP for products with single‐country and multicountry supply chains are statistically different, meaning that simplifying a multicountry label by listing only the country where the ingredients are grown or only the country where the ingredients are processed can result in different consumer values. We also find that for countries with a poor quality reputation, consumers respond more negatively when that country has the “last touch” than when that country's involvement is limited to upstream supply chain links. 相似文献
63.
64.
Jason Heyes 《英国劳资关系杂志》1996,34(3):351-369
Managerial strategies designed to elicit greater employee commitment in production have received much attention in recent industrial relations reseach. Training is seen to form a core component of such strategies, yielding such beneficial outcomes as improved efficiency and employee motivation. Yet the connections between training strategy and performance outcomes have been treated in an overly simplistic fashion. This in turn reflects a lack of empirical inquiry at the level of the shop-floor currently to be found in the subject area. By integrating an investigation of the workplace into the analysis of management strategy and performance outcomes, it is possible to develop a deeper understanding of the linkages between training provision, commitment and systems of reward. 相似文献
65.
Jason Oakes 《Journal of Bioeconomics》2016,18(2):137-151
I am interested in how models, practices, and concepts travel across specialties and thereby change and are changed in turn. In the present essay I discuss Gordon Tullock’s ideas about the relationship between biology and economics in the light of his correspondence with the biologist Garrett Hardin. Tullock contributed to one of Hardin’s edited projects, but they took different approaches to related problems, which I characterize as problems of coordinated action. Tullock saw that he and Hardin were up to a similar line of inquiry, and Hardin engaged with him up to a point, but ultimately the biologist differed with the economist regarding the potential for the reliability of a regulating power such as the state. 相似文献
66.
Kalle A. Piirainen Tuomas Raivio Kaisa Lähteenmäki-Smith Lars Alkaersig Jason Li-Ying 《Technology Analysis & Strategic Management》2018,30(3):268-281
This paper presents an empirical account of a phenomenon that we refer to as the ‘reverse tragedy of the commons’ in open innovation. The name signifies the ‘under-exploitation’ of intellectual property (IP) under weak appropriability. The name is this graphic because the tragedy is costly, and can also render IP effectively worthless and block innovation in the short to medium term. We propose that the tragedy is borne out of the interaction between enterprise characteristics, a competitive setting and the framework that is set by the policy intervention. This finding is pertinent to policy-makers with regard to the design of research, development and innovation instruments, as well as managers who must determine how to implement open practices in innovation. 相似文献
67.
Scientists have argued that invasive species can be managed most cost effectively with greater investments in prevention. Further, under ideas like the precautionary principle it is reasonable to expect that a cautious manager would use more prevention relative to control because it keeps more invaders out. Yet, this is not typically done. In many cases, private and public resources are invested primarily to control existing invaders rather than to prevent new invasions. Managers frequently wait until after invaders have arrived and then scramble to limit the damages. We believe these paradoxical decisions can be understood by recognizing the link between typical human preferences for risk bearing and the technology of risk reduction. We demonstrate quantitatively how managers perceived to be cautious or averse to risk tend to shy away from prevention relative to control. This counterintuitive result arises because control is a safer choice than prevention because its productivity is relatively less risky: it works to remove existing invaders from the system. In contrast, the productivity of prevention is more uncertain because prevention only reduces the chance of invasion, it does not eliminate it, and invasion may not occur even in the absence of prevention. Managers' averse to risk will inherently avoid as much uncertainty as possible, whether the source of uncertainty regards ecological outcomes or economic productivity. Implications for environmental decision making are clear. In invasive species management, if managers act as though they are risk averse, their caution can backfire when it leads to more control rather than prevention. The social consequences of this choice are a greater probability of future invasions and lower social welfare. Our results suggest that social welfare is highest when managers were willing to “take a risk” with prevention. 相似文献
68.
69.
Jason Barr 《Real Estate Economics》2010,38(3):567-597
This article investigates the market for skyscrapers in Manhattan from 1895 to 2004. Clark and Kingston (1930) have argued that extreme height is a result of profit maximization, while Helsley and Strange (2008) posit that skyscraper height can be caused, in part, by strategic interaction among builders. I provide a model for the market for building height and the number of completions, which are functions of the market fundamentals and the desire of builders to stand out in the skyline. I test this model using time series data. I find that skyscraper completions and average heights over the 20th century are consistent with profit maximization; the desire to add extra height to stand out does not appear to be a systematic determinant of building height. 相似文献
70.
Advances in Drama Theory for Managing Global Hazards and Disasters. Part II: Coping with Global Climate Change and Environmental Catastrophe 总被引:2,自引:0,他引:2
We explore issues of group decision making for reducing global environmental risk, with particular reference to the political
dynamics surrounding international agreements on tackling climate change. Continuing political delays in deciding to reduce
greenhouse gas emissions may make it necessary to resort to high risk and controversial geo-engineering solutions, such as
injecting large amounts of sulfur dioxide into the stratosphere, despite the unforeseen, potentially catastrophic consequences
that these entail. Advances in drama theory (dt.2) are used to analyze the prospects for agreement on reducing or stabilizing
greenhouse gas emissions, following the Bali agreement of December 2007. It is concluded that Western nations and emerging
economies are behaving like players in a game of “chicken”, each expecting the other to take on the main burden of emissions
reduction. We judge it unlikely that either will play a full part until it is too late for emissions reduction alone to avert
environmental catastrophe. At that point, parties will resort to geo-engineering “fixes”, despite the risks. However, all
such forecasts are conditional on decisions made and attitudes taken by political leaders and the public. Our analysis serves
to pinpoint the relevant decisions and attitudes. 相似文献