全文获取类型
收费全文 | 18872篇 |
免费 | 1266篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 3817篇 |
工业经济 | 1481篇 |
计划管理 | 3349篇 |
经济学 | 4089篇 |
综合类 | 161篇 |
运输经济 | 206篇 |
旅游经济 | 269篇 |
贸易经济 | 3555篇 |
农业经济 | 909篇 |
经济概况 | 2288篇 |
信息产业经济 | 2篇 |
邮电经济 | 12篇 |
出版年
2023年 | 78篇 |
2021年 | 168篇 |
2020年 | 363篇 |
2019年 | 743篇 |
2018年 | 558篇 |
2017年 | 700篇 |
2016年 | 668篇 |
2015年 | 579篇 |
2014年 | 702篇 |
2013年 | 2170篇 |
2012年 | 758篇 |
2011年 | 811篇 |
2010年 | 740篇 |
2009年 | 644篇 |
2008年 | 629篇 |
2007年 | 533篇 |
2006年 | 489篇 |
2005年 | 399篇 |
2004年 | 388篇 |
2003年 | 383篇 |
2002年 | 372篇 |
2001年 | 369篇 |
2000年 | 357篇 |
1999年 | 320篇 |
1998年 | 313篇 |
1997年 | 271篇 |
1996年 | 236篇 |
1995年 | 232篇 |
1994年 | 246篇 |
1993年 | 248篇 |
1992年 | 273篇 |
1991年 | 259篇 |
1990年 | 205篇 |
1989年 | 185篇 |
1988年 | 171篇 |
1987年 | 170篇 |
1986年 | 172篇 |
1985年 | 246篇 |
1984年 | 257篇 |
1983年 | 251篇 |
1982年 | 217篇 |
1981年 | 200篇 |
1980年 | 175篇 |
1979年 | 175篇 |
1978年 | 159篇 |
1977年 | 138篇 |
1976年 | 125篇 |
1975年 | 141篇 |
1974年 | 102篇 |
1973年 | 103篇 |
排序方式: 共有10000条查询结果,搜索用时 13 毫秒
11.
Sebouh Aintablian Patricia A. Mcgraw Gordon S. Roberts 《Journal of Business Finance & Accounting》2007,34(1-2):389-401
Abstract: Loan announcement effects for 152 Canadian companies are examined to investigate the efficiency of monitoring by banks facing lender environmental liability. Market reaction to the announcement of bank debt to 'environmental' firms is more positive and significant than for 'non-environmental' firms and, for firms in industries with a higher likelihood of experiencing spill events, is more positive and significant, reinforcing earlier results that establish a relationship between specific loan/borrower characteristics and announcement period excess returns and providing further evidence on the 'uniqueness' of bank loans by demonstrating the superior ability of banks to monitor corporate borrowers exposed to environmental liability. 相似文献
12.
13.
14.
15.
In this paper we consider the potential gain of a government pursuing a two-part trade policy: an import license for entry, along with a per-unit tariff on imports. The model is a two-stage game of complete but imperfect information. In the first stage, the domestic government sets trade policy, while in the second stage the home and foreign producers behave as Cournot competitors. The paper demonstrates that the optimal trade policy depends upon the number of firms, the degree of heterogeneity in cost functions, and the degree of convexity in cost functions. 相似文献
16.
Paul S. J. Wymenga 《Bulletin of Indonesian Economic Studies》1991,27(1):127-153
Around the mid-1980s, Indonesia's protectionist regime supported an industrial structure in which industries were mainly oriented towards producing for the domestic market. Since then, trade policies have shifted to a more outward-looking strategy, stimulating the growth and diversification of non-oil manufactured exports. This paper attempts to quantify the nominal and effective rates of protection resulting from trade policies at the end of the 1980s. After an introduction in which the 1989 trade policies are discussed, estimates of nominal and effective rates of protection are presented. It is shown that though the level of protection has declined since 1987, it still varies widely across economic sectors. Furthermore, despite the more open trade strategy, the paper's findings show that the trade regime remains biased against exports. Finally, by examining some trade policy issues, the paper presents further ways of rationalising the structure of protection in Indonesia's industrial sector. 相似文献
17.
We argue that firms with interdependent worker productivity, team production, have a higher cost of absence and, as a consequence, spend additional resources on monitoring absence. As a result, firms with team production should have lower absence rates. We estimate the determinants of absence for blue‐collar workers using a sample of German manufacturing establishments. Workplace teams are used as a proxy for team production. The estimates reveal that firms with teams have lower absence rates, as do smaller establishments. The size effect, however, is unique to establishments with teams, which fits prior theoretical work that has not been previously tested. 相似文献
18.
The margin system is the first line of defense against the default risk of a clearinghouse. From the perspectives of a clearinghouse, the utmost concern is to have a prudential system to control the default exposure. Once the level of prudentiality is set, the next concern will be the opportunity cost of the investors, because high opportunity cost discourages people from hedging futures, and thus defeats the function of a futures market. In this article, we first develop different measures of prudentiality and opportunity cost. We then formulate a statistical framework to evaluate different margin‐setting methodologies, all of which strike a balance between prudentiality and opportunity cost. Three margin‐setting methodologies, namely, (1) using simple moving averages; (2) using exponentially weighted moving averages; (3) using a GARCH approach, are applied to the Hang Seng Index futures. Keeping the same prudentiality level, it is shown that the one using a GARCH approach by and large gives the lowest average overcharge. © 2004 Wiley Periodicals, Inc. Jrl Fut Mark 24:117–145, 2004 相似文献
19.
This article uses a nonparametric test based on the arc‐sine law (see, e.g., Feller, 1965 ), which involves comparing the theoretical distribution implied by an intraday random walk with the empirical frequency distribution of the daily high/low times, in order to address the question of whether the abandonment of pit trading has been associated with greater market efficiency. If market inefficiencies result from flaws in the market microstructure of pit trading, they ought to have been eliminated by the introduction of screen trading. If, on the other hand, the inefficiencies are a reflection of investor psychology, they are likely to have survived, unaffected by the changeover. We focus here on four cases. Both the FTSE‐100 and CAC‐40 index futures contracts were originally traded by open outcry and have moved over to electronic trading in recent years, so that we are able to compare pricing behavior before and after the changeover. The equivalent contracts in Germany and Korea, on the other hand, have been traded electronically ever since their inception. Our results overwhelmingly reject the random‐walk hypothesis both for open‐outcry and electronic‐trading data sets, suggesting there has been no increase in efficiency as a result of the introduction of screen trading. One possible explanation consistent with our results would be that the index futures market is characterized by intraday overreaction. © 2004 Wiley Periodicals, Inc. Jrl Fut Mark 24:337–357, 2004 相似文献
20.
This article analyzes the effects of the length of hedging horizon on the optimal hedge ratio and hedging effectiveness using 9 different hedging horizons and 25 different commodities. We discuss the concept of short‐ and long‐run hedge ratios and propose a technique to simultaneously estimate them. The empirical results indicate that the short‐run hedge ratios are significantly less than 1 and increase with the length of hedging horizon. We also find that hedging effectiveness increases with the length of hedging horizon. However, the long‐run hedge ratio is found to be close to the naïve hedge ratio of unity. This implies that, if the hedging horizon is long, then the naïve hedge ratio is close to the optimum hedge ratio. © 2004 Wiley Periodicals, Inc. Jrl Fut Mark 24:359–386, 2004 相似文献