全文获取类型
收费全文 | 8707篇 |
免费 | 148篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 1845篇 |
工业经济 | 637篇 |
计划管理 | 1366篇 |
经济学 | 1839篇 |
综合类 | 113篇 |
运输经济 | 56篇 |
旅游经济 | 171篇 |
贸易经济 | 1358篇 |
农业经济 | 309篇 |
经济概况 | 1155篇 |
邮电经济 | 6篇 |
出版年
2020年 | 83篇 |
2019年 | 122篇 |
2018年 | 153篇 |
2017年 | 161篇 |
2016年 | 147篇 |
2015年 | 108篇 |
2014年 | 148篇 |
2013年 | 974篇 |
2012年 | 223篇 |
2011年 | 254篇 |
2010年 | 220篇 |
2009年 | 237篇 |
2008年 | 233篇 |
2007年 | 191篇 |
2006年 | 192篇 |
2005年 | 165篇 |
2004年 | 170篇 |
2003年 | 166篇 |
2002年 | 177篇 |
2001年 | 162篇 |
2000年 | 161篇 |
1999年 | 152篇 |
1998年 | 166篇 |
1997年 | 160篇 |
1996年 | 148篇 |
1995年 | 119篇 |
1994年 | 124篇 |
1993年 | 139篇 |
1992年 | 158篇 |
1991年 | 160篇 |
1990年 | 113篇 |
1989年 | 114篇 |
1988年 | 96篇 |
1987年 | 112篇 |
1986年 | 121篇 |
1985年 | 158篇 |
1984年 | 135篇 |
1983年 | 165篇 |
1982年 | 135篇 |
1981年 | 123篇 |
1980年 | 140篇 |
1979年 | 125篇 |
1978年 | 94篇 |
1977年 | 109篇 |
1976年 | 101篇 |
1975年 | 100篇 |
1974年 | 91篇 |
1973年 | 73篇 |
1972年 | 62篇 |
1971年 | 61篇 |
排序方式: 共有8855条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
151.
C. Imbriani R. Pittiglio F. Reganati E. Sica 《International Advances in Economic Research》2014,20(1):57-72
The absorptive capacity—the ability of enterprises to efficiently absorb and internalise knowledge from outside sources—represents the link between firms’ capabilities to implement new products and the external stock of technological opportunities, such as those gleamed from Multinational Enterprises (MNEs). This paper explores whether the effect of foreign direct investment (FDI) on the productivity of Italian domestically-owned firms (DOFs) is dependent on their absorptive capacity. In particular, given the peculiar characteristics of the Italian productive system, our analysis focuses on three different dimensions of the absorptive capacity: the size of the technological gap between foreign-owned firms (FOFs) and DOFs, firm size, and the regional distribution of firms. Our findings suggest that technological gap and firm size matter considerably for the spillover effect. Moreover, spillovers exhibit a sub-national dimension present only in the northeastern region of the peninsula. 相似文献
152.
153.
154.
The threat of future entry affects the exploitation of common property resources in important ways. An incumbent has a strategic incentive to manipulate the resource stock to deter entry or to harvest more stock prior to entry rather than share the resource with the entrant. It is possible that the threat of potential entry can lead to the extinction of the resource even though actual competition would result in a steady state with a positive stock level. 相似文献
155.
156.
157.
Over the three decades leading up to the crisis of 2008, inequality dramatically increased in the United States and Great Britain. What stands out, but is seldom noted, is that this occurred within democracies where the relative losers—the overwhelming majority—could in principle have used the political system to block or reverse rising inequality. Why did they not do so? A glance at history reveals that peoples have only very infrequently contested inequality because they were led to believe that their inferior status in terms of income, wealth, and privilege was just, that it was not really so bad, or that it was necessary for their future well‐being. Ideological systems legitimated a status quo of inequality, or in more modern times even increasing inequality. This article surveys the manner in which inequality has been historically legitimated, first predominantly by religion, then predominately by economic thought. Attention is then focused on the manner in which contemporary economic science and its popular interpretations in the media have served to legitimate inequality in the U.S. since the mid‐1970s. The article concludes with a reflection on the unique conditions that enable the legitimation of inequality to be delegitimated. 相似文献
158.
Monica C. Jackson Adria Trotman Melissa Stephens Kimberly F. Sellers 《Quality and Quantity》2013,47(1):15-26
In numerous psychology studies, subjects are asked to perform some task a number of times, T. The effect of the choice of T on the associated inference, however, is usually not assessed. We investigate the appropriate choice of T empirically by using data collected in a study on the relationship between psychopathy and risk-taking in 90 inner city drug users enrolled in a residential treatment program. We show that, when studying this relationship, the latency variable usually discarded from the analysis behaves exponentially allowing a natural division of the study period 1, . . . , T into two distinct subperiods. These subperiods yield significantly different results—in the early period only (which we call “reactive”), subjects with high psychopathy scores exhibit lower sensitivity to reward and punishment in our risk taking experiment. The later period (which we call “stable”) shows no relationship between sensitivity to reward and punishment and psychopathic tendencies. 相似文献
159.
In the context of linear multi-factor models, this study proposes an egalitarian, optimal and unique procedure to find orthogonalized factors, which also facilitates the decomposition of the coefficient of determination. Importantly, the new risk factors may diverge significantly from the original ones. The decomposition of risk allows one to explicitly examine the impact of individual factors on the return variation of risky assets, which provides discriminative power for factor selection. The procedure is experimentally robust even for small samples. Empirically we find that even though, on average, approximately eighty (sixty-five) percent of style (industry) portfolios’ volatility is explained by the market and size factors, other factors such as value, momentum and contrarian still play an important role for certain portfolios. The components of systematic risk, while dynamic over time, generally exhibit negative correlation between market, on one side, and size, value, momentum and contrarian, on the other side. 相似文献
160.
Robert F. Mulligan 《The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance》2013,53(4):450-459
Hyman Minsky's Financial Instability Hypothesis (FIH) is applied to various North American Industrial Classification System (NAICS) industry groups, and it is found that some sectors develop much more closely in accordance with the FIH than others. Minsky categorized firms based on the relationship between cash flow and debt service requirements: hedge finance units, whose operating revenues are adequate to service current interest and principal on their debt; speculative finance units, which can meet interest payments but cannot pay down principal; and Ponzi finance units, which cannot meet current interest payments. The FIH is related to, as well as supportive of, Austrian Business Cycle (ABC) theory, because interest rates are negatively correlated with the proportion and market value of speculative firms in several sectors. 相似文献