首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   16872篇
  免费   397篇
财政金融   3556篇
工业经济   1230篇
计划管理   2608篇
经济学   3739篇
综合类   203篇
运输经济   114篇
旅游经济   244篇
贸易经济   2659篇
农业经济   771篇
经济概况   2130篇
信息产业经济   2篇
邮电经济   13篇
  2021年   100篇
  2020年   228篇
  2019年   294篇
  2018年   400篇
  2017年   412篇
  2016年   374篇
  2015年   243篇
  2014年   403篇
  2013年   1813篇
  2012年   473篇
  2011年   578篇
  2010年   521篇
  2009年   525篇
  2008年   492篇
  2007年   434篇
  2006年   399篇
  2005年   329篇
  2004年   323篇
  2003年   302篇
  2002年   309篇
  2001年   306篇
  2000年   338篇
  1999年   328篇
  1998年   347篇
  1997年   317篇
  1996年   276篇
  1995年   251篇
  1994年   274篇
  1993年   290篇
  1992年   321篇
  1991年   296篇
  1990年   253篇
  1989年   217篇
  1988年   217篇
  1987年   203篇
  1986年   194篇
  1985年   288篇
  1984年   298篇
  1983年   301篇
  1982年   257篇
  1981年   237篇
  1980年   203篇
  1979年   207篇
  1978年   185篇
  1977年   152篇
  1976年   152篇
  1975年   163篇
  1974年   113篇
  1973年   124篇
  1972年   91篇
排序方式: 共有10000条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
21.
22.
23.
The notion that prices impound a wide array of information, including market expectations, has led to earnings forecast models conditioned on prices. Yet, presumably, analysts' forecasts capture both public information and certain private information not previously impounded in prices. Accordingly, price-based models are seemingly an inefficient, and less effective, source of expecta-tions. This article investigates this hypothesis using financial analysts', price-based, and naive forecasts. Results indicate that analysts' forecasts (1) are at least as accurate as price-based and naive models, and (2) yield better expectations for market tests relating returns and earnings. These inferences are robust across different information environments. The evidence suggests that analysts either possess private information or are more effective information processors, or both.  相似文献   
24.
25.
26.
Popular monthly coincident indices of business cycles, e.g. the composite index and the Stock–Watson coincident index, have two shortcomings. First, they ignore information contained in quarterly indicators such as real GDP. Second, they lack economic interpretation; hence the heights of peaks and the depths of troughs depend on the choice of an index. This paper extends the Stock–Watson coincident index by applying maximum likelihood factor analysis to a mixed‐frequency series of quarterly real GDP and monthly coincident business cycle indicators. The resulting index is related to latent monthly real GDP. Copyright © 2002 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.  相似文献   
27.
28.
Transition patterns from school to work differ considerably across OECD countries. Some countries exhibit high youth unemployment rates, which can be considered an indicator of the difficulty facing young people trying to integrate into the labour market. At the same time, education is a time‐consuming process, and enrolment and dropout decisions depend on expected duration of studies as well as on job prospects with and without completed degrees. One way to model entry into the labour market is by means of job‐search models, where the job arrival hazard is a key parameter in capturing the ease or difficulty in finding a job. Standard models of job search and education assume that skills can be upgraded instantaneously (and mostly in the form of on‐the‐job training) at a fixed cost. This paper models education as a time‐consuming process, a concept which we call time‐to‐educate, during which an individual faces the trade‐off between continuing education and taking up a job.  相似文献   
29.
This study examines the long memory behavior in gold returns during the post-Bretton Woods period using a new rescaled range technique. Unlike the conventional rescaled range analysis, the new rescaled range analysis is robust to short-term dependence and conditional heteroscedasticity found in the gold data. Statistical results suggest that the long memory behavior in gold returns is rather unstable. When only few observations corresponding to major political events in the Middle East, together with the Hunts event, in late 1979 are omitted, little evidence of long memory can be found.  相似文献   
30.
An Erratum for this article has been published in Journal of Applied Econometrics 18(2) 2003, 249 Previous empirical work on corporate growth rates using cross‐section or short‐panel econometric techniques suggests that growth rates are random but that some degree of mean reversion exists. This means that size differences between firms are transitory. Another, more natural way to explore the long‐run distribution of firm sizes is to examine data on the growth of particular firms over long periods of time. Using a sample of 147 UK firms observed continually for more than 30 years, our conclusions are that growth rates are highly variable over time and that differences in growth rates between firms do not persist for very long. Further, firms show no tendency to converge to either a common size or to a pattern of stable size differences over time. These results are compared and contrasted with standard approaches that suggest that firms reach and maintain stable positions in a skewed size distribution. Copyright © 2002 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号